Skip to main content
Log in

Candidacy rules and party unity: The impact of multiple candidacies on legislative voting behaviour in Italy

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Acta Politica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A common approach among scholars is depicting electoral democracy as a two-round competition for offices, starting with elections and continuing with the allocation of legislative offices among legislators. But what happens when the allocation of seats does not end at Round 1 (elections), but continues as a first stage of Round 2? This may occur when candidacy rules allow candidates to be nominated and elected in more than one district. Multiple candidacies create a pool of vacant parliamentary seats, whose allocation depends mostly on party leaders’ choices. Multi-candidacies increase therefore the centralization of candidate selection process, granting leaders greater post-election influence and decreasing the incentives to vote against party line for those MPs whose parliamentary office depends mostly on the leaders’ will. Data on legislators’ voting behaviour in the Italian Chamber of Deputies (2006–2011) support this notion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is a partial list of the most relevant works in the area: Becher and Sieberer (2008), Carey (2007), Desposato (2006), Ferrara (2004), Herron (2002), Hix (2004), Jun and Hix (2010), Shugart et al (2005), Sieberer (2010), Thames (2005).

  2. Analysing voting behaviour in three Italian legislatures (13th–15th), Curini et al (2011) did not find any empirical evidence of the validity of Tavit’s argument in Italy.

  3. Dual candidacy is frequent both in mixed-member majoritarian systems, like Japan and Italy from 1993 to 2005 (Di Virgilio and Reed, 2011), and in mixed-member proportional ones, such as Germany and New Zealand (Ferrara et al, 2005).

  4. As in Finland during the 1950s, The Netherlands and Italy. The range of electoral systems allowing candidates to be nominated in more than one district includes also the single transferable vote used in Malta.

  5. In The Netherlands, for example, candidates who win a seat in more than one district are declared elected in the district in which they received most preference votes (Andeweg, 2005, p. 498).

  6. Legislature 15th ended prematurely, lasting only 2 years (2006–2008). We limit our analysis to the first 3 years of Legislature 16th (2008–2011), from the beginning to November 2011, when the Prime Minister Silvio Berlusconi announced his resignation. The Berlusconi IV government was replaced by a full technocratic cabinet led by Mario Monti, supported by almost all of the parties in the parliament. Given the extraordinary nature of the relationship between the government and the parliament during the year of the Monti cabinet (Pedrazzani and Pinto, 2013), we opt for excluding this period from our analysis.

  7. The Democratic Party was created in 2007 by the merger of DS and The Daisy (DL) – the party to which Giuseppe Fioroni belonged.

  8. The bonus-adjusted proportional system replaced a mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) electoral system that had been adopted in 1993. The MMM electoral system allowed a candidate to be nominated in both the PR and the plurality tier at the same time. Moreover, candidacy rules made it possible for a candidate to be included in up to 3 out of 26 multi-member districts in the PR tier. Conversely, in the pre-1993 PR system – employed in Italy in nine general elections from 1958 to 1992 – candidacy rules made it possible for a candidate to be included in up to 3 out of 31 multi-member districts. During this period, the candidacy rule provisions never worked as a real strategic device. The pre-1993 PR system was an open list one in which voters had multiple preferential votes within the party list: consequently, those votes determined which candidates were elected. To some extent, the open list made the up-to-three candidacy rule ineffective.

  9. Excluding abstentions from the computation of defections produces similar results in our analysis.

  10. Voting records for the Chamber of Deputies are available only starting from 1987 onwards (Borghetto et al, 2012).

  11. Studying the US Congress, Nokken (2009) suggested that final-passage votes are not particularly important for passage, since skilled politicians should be able to structure things before the vote in such a way that bills are approved in any case. In this way, dissidents can vote sincerely without endangering bills’ approval. Given the strong government-opposition dynamics of parliamentary systems, rebellions cannot be neglected, even if they are not determinant for the vote: they harm party reputation and weaken the majority supporting the government.

  12. We duplicate observations also for legislators who jumped from the motley mixed group to another party. For legislators who switched party in the last days of the period under investigation, we consider only the first affiliation.

  13. Party switching is not a big concern during Legislature 15th, but, if not addressed correctly, it could constitute a potential source of problems during Legislature 16th (see Di Virgilio et al, 2012).

  14. Data on multiple candidacies have been recostructed on the basis of the information available in the Italian Historical Archive of Elections (http://elezionistorico.interno.it/, see also Di Virgilio, 2012).

  15. In each legislature, we code as new parties political formations that either contested their first elections in the ballot immediately preceding the start of the term or form during the legislative cycle. Parties resulting from a merger of existing political formations are coded as new ones.

  16. Party leaders, in particular those who have responsibilities in the party organization, are also more likely to miss parliamentary votes.

  17. A β-binomial model constitutes a possible alternative (Tavits, 2009). However, the β distribution ignores 0s and 1s in the outcome variable, while our sample is largely composed by 0s (see Table 3). We employ also a β-binomial model on our data. Results do not substantially change.

  18. Legislators are also clustered in different parties. However, in non-linear models, adding a full set of parties’ dummies to check for party fixed-effect could lead to what is known as the incidental parameter problem (Kalbfleisch and Sprott, 1970). Similarly, using clustered standard errors on parties could make our estimators worse if clusters are few and highly unbalanced, as in our case. Thus, we prefer to model directly the effect of legislative groups on defections including in our analysis variables related directly to party characteristics, such as size, government status and organizational attributes. Notwithstanding, including party dummies or clustering for parties does not modify substantially our results.

  19. Sieberer (2006) found a similar result using party cohesion scores: on average, larger parties show higher unity than smaller ones. This happens despite the bias in the Rice index reported by Desposato (2003, 2005), which tends to inflate small parties’ cohesion scores, making them appear more cohesive than they are. However, this problem is not vital in our study. First, our analysis focuses on the individual share of defections and not on party cohesion scores. Second, the bias is more evident in parties with very few members (<10), while in our study most of the parliamentary groups are composed by at least 20 members.

  20. The draft limits to eight, the maximum number of multiple candidacies.

References

  • Andeweg, R.B. (2005) The Netherlands: The sanctity of proportionality. In: M. Gallagher and P. Mitchell (eds.) The Politics of Electoral Systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 491–510.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • André, A., Depauw, S. and Martin, S. (2014) Electoral systems and legislators’ constituency effort: The mediating effect of electoral vulnerability. Comparative Political Studies 48(4): 464–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnes, S. (1977) Representation in Italy: Institutionalized Tradition and Electoral Choice. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becher, M. and Sieberer, U. (2008) Discipline, electoral rules and defection in the Bundestag, 1983–94. German Politics 17(3): 293–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benedetto, G. and Hix, S. (2007) The rejected, the ejected, and the dejected: Rebels in the 2001–2005 British House of Commons. Comparative Political Studies 40(7): 755–781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolleyer, N. (2013) New Parties in old Party Systems: Persistence and Decline in Seventeen Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Borghetto, E., Curini, L., Giuliani, M., Pellegata, A. and Zucchini, F. (2012) Italian law-making archive: A new tool for the analysis of the Italian legislative process. Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica 42(3): 481–502.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J.M. (2007) Competing principals, political institutions, and party unity in legislative voting. American Journal of Political Science 51(1): 92–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J.M. and Shugart, M.S. (1995) Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: A rank ordering of electoral formulas. Electoral Studies 14(4): 417–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, R., Cox, G.W. and Pachón, M. (2006) How parties create electoral democracy, Chapter 2Legislative Studies Quarterly 31(2): 153–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrubba, C.J., Gabel, M., Murrah, L., Clough, R., Montgomery, E. and Schambach, R. (2006) Off the record: Unrecorded legislative votes, selection bias and roll-call vote analysis. British Journal of Political Science 36(4): 691–704.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiru, M. (2015) Multiple candidacies and the role of the lowest electoral tier for individualized campaigning. East European Politics and Societies 20(10): 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cotta, M. and Verzichelli, L. (2007) Political Institutions in Italy. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G.W. and McCubbins, M.D. (1993) Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L. and Zucchini, F. (2010) Testing the law-making theories in a parliamentary democracy. A roll call analysis of the Italian Chamber of Deputies (1988–2008). In: T. König, G. Tsebelis and M. Debus (eds.) Reform Processes and Policy Change: Veto Players and Decision-Making in Modern Democracies. New York: Springer, pp. 189–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L., Marangoni, F. and Tronconi, F. (2011) Rebels with a cause – But which one? Defections from legislative party unity in Italy and their individual and institutional determinants. Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica 41(1): 385–409.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Micheli, C. and Verzichelli, L. (2004) Il Parlamento. Bologna, Italy: Il mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Depauw, S. and Martin, S. (2009) Legislative party discipline and cohesion in comparative perspective. In: D. Giannetti and K. Benoit (eds.) Intra-Party Politics and Coalition Governments in Parliamentary Democracies. London, New York: Routledge, pp. 103–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desposato, S.W. (2003) Comparing group and subgroup cohesion scores: A nonparametric method with an application to Brazil. Political Analysis 11(3): 275–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desposato, S.W. (2005) Correcting for small group inflation of roll-call cohesion scores. British Journal of Political Science 35(4): 731–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desposato, S.W. (2006) The impact of electoral rules on legislative parties: Lessons from the Brazilian senate and chamber of deputies. The Journal of Politics 68(4): 1018–1030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Virgilio, A. (2012) Electoral systems, candidacy rules and democratic representation. The case of multi-candidacies in Italy. Paper presented at the 40st ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops, University of Antwerp, Antwerp, 10–15 April.

  • Di Virgilio, A. and Reed, S.R. (2011) Nominating candidates under new rules in Italy and Japan: You cannot bargain with resources you do not have. In: D. Giannetti and B. Grofman (eds.) A Natural Experiment on Electoral Law Reform: Evaluating the Long Run Consequences of 1990s Electoral Reform in Italy and Japan. New York: Springer, pp. 59–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Virgilio, A., Giannetti, D. and Pinto, L. (2012) Patterns of party switching in the Italian chamber of deputies 2008–2011. Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica 42(1): 29–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fenno, R.F. (1978) Home Style: House Members in Their Districts. Boston, MA: Little Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara, F. (2004) Frogs, mice and mixed electoral institutions: Party discipline in Italy’s XIV chamber of deputies. The Journal of Legislative Studies 10(4): 10–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara, F., Herron, E.S. and Nishikawa, M. (2005) Mixed Electoral Systems: Contamination and its Consequences. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Haspel, M., Remington, T.F. and Smith, S.S. (1998) Electoral institutions and party cohesion in the Russian Duma. The Journal of Politics 60(2): 417–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, W.B. and Mershon, C. (2005) Party switching in the Italian chamber of deputies, 1996–2001. The Journal of Politics 67(2): 536–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, W.B. and Mershon, C. (2008) Dealing in discipline: Party switching and legislative voting in the Italian chamber of deputies, 1988–2000. American Journal of Political Science 52(4): 910–924.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herron, E.S. (2002) Electoral influences on legislative in mixed-member systems: From Ukraine’s Verkhovna Rada. Legislative Studies Quarterly 27(3): 361–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hix, S. (2004) Electoral institutions and legislative behavior: Explaining voting defection in the European parliament. World Politics 56(2): 194–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hix, S., Noury, A. and Roland, G. (2005) Power to the parties: Cohesion and competition in the European parliament, 1979–2001. British Journal of Political Science 35(2): 209–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hug, S. (2010) Selection effects in roll call votes. British Journal of Political Science 40(1): 225–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jun, H.-W. and Hix, S. (2010) Electoral systems, political career paths and legislative behavior: Evidence from South Korea’s mixed-member system. Japanese Journal of Political Science 11(2): 153–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalbfleisch, J.D. and Sprott, D.A. (1970) Application of likelihood methods to models involving large numbers of parameters. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B (Methodological) 32(2): 175–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, S. (2014) Why electoral systems don’t always matter: The impact of ‘mega-seats’ on legislative behaviour in Ireland. Party Politics 20(3): 467–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, D.R. (1974) Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nokken, T.P. (2009) Party switching and the procedural party agenda in the US house of representatives. In: W.B. Heller and C. Mershon (eds.) Political Parties and Legislative Party Switching. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 81–108.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Panebianco, A. (1988) Political Parties: Organization and Power. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Papke, L.E. and Wooldridge, J.M. (1996) Econometric methods for fractional response variables with an application to 401(k) plan participation rates. Journal of Applied Econometrics 11(6): 619–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papke, L.E. and Wooldridge, J.M. (2008) Panel data methods for fractional response variables with an application to test pass rates. Journal of Econometrics 145(1–2): 121–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedrazzani, A. and Pinto, L. (2013) The work of parliament in the year of the technocratic government. Italian Politics 28(1): 153–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pinto, L. (2015) The time path of legislative party switching and the dynamics of political competition: The Italian case (1996–2011). The Journal of Legislative Studies 21(3): 323–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rahat, G. and Hazan, R.Y. (2001) Candidate selection methods: An analytical framework. Party Politics 7(3): 297–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shomer, Y. (2009) Candidate selection procedures, seniority, and vote-seeking behavior. Comparative Political Studies 42(7): 945–970.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M.S. and Wattenberg, M.P. (eds.) (2003) Mixed-Member Electoral Systems: The Best of Both Worlds?. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M.S., Valdini, M.E. and Suominen, K. (2005) Looking for locals: Voter information demands and personal vote-earning attributes of legislators under proportional representation. American Journal of Political Science 49(2): 437–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sieberer, U. (2006) Party unity in parliamentary democracies: A comparative analysis. The Journal of Legislative Studies 12(2): 150–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sieberer, U. (2010) Behavioral consequences of mixed electoral systems: Deviating voting behavior of district and list MPs in the German Bundestag. Electoral Studies 29(3): 484–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavits, M. (2009) The making of mavericks: Local loyalties and party defection. Comparative Political Studies 42(6): 793–815.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavits, M. (2010) Effect of local ties on electoral success and parliamentary behaviour: The case of Estonia. Party Politics 16(2): 215–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thames, F.C. (2001) Legislative voting behaviour in the Russian duma: Understanding the effect of mandate. Europe-Asia Studies 53(6): 869–884.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thames, F.C. (2005) A house divided: Party strength and the mandate divide in Hungary, Russia, and Ukraine. Comparative Political Studies 38(3): 282–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thames, F.C. (2007) Discipline and party institutionalization in post-soviet legislatures. Party Politics 13(4): 456–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This article has been originally conceived with Aldo Di Virgilio, who prematurely passed away on February 2015. He was among the first scholars to recognize the importance of multiple candidacies in Italy and significantly contributed to an earlier version of this paper, which was presented at the 4th Annual General Conference of the European Political Science Association (EPSA), Edinburgh, 19–21 June, 2013. This work owes much to the research carried out by Aldo Di Virgilio, who, with his attention for details and for the links binding rules and political competition, has been an invaluable guidance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luca Pinto.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pinto, L. Candidacy rules and party unity: The impact of multiple candidacies on legislative voting behaviour in Italy. Acta Polit 52, 43–63 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1057/ap.2015.24

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/ap.2015.24

Keywords

Navigation