Introduction

The decoy effect may well be one of the most famous of human biases (Frederick et al., 2014) that violates neoclassical economics’ rational choice theory (Pettibone, 2012). According to a large body of literature (see, for example, Huber et al., 1982; Huber and Puto, 1983; Ratneshwar et al., 1987; Simonson, 1989; Tversky and Kahneman, 1991; Tversky and Simonson, 1992; Ariely and Wallsten, 1995; Heath and Chatterjee, 1995; Wedell and Pettibone, 1996; Sen, 1998; Kivetz et al., 2004; Ariely, 2008; Frederick et al., 2014; Lynn and Yang, 2014), people may be induced to switch from one offer to another by the presence of a third option, the so-called decoy, that rationally should not be of influence in the decision-making process (Huber et al., 1982). The decoy has to be chosen such that it looks alike, yet is slightly inferior, to the target option to impart an effect. Note that the inferiority of the decoy ensures that it is not chosen itself. Under these circumstances, the introduction of a decoy has been shown to increase the choice share of the target option. This decoy (or “asymmetric dominance”) effect clearly violates the “axiom of regularity” of rational choice theory: when given a choice set A, where AB, the probability of choosing an element x from B cannot be greater than the probability of choosing x from A (Luce, 1959; Yang, 2013).

Although a large number of studies have demonstrated the decoy effect in various settings over the last few decades (see Huber et al., 2014, for an overview), some these studies have recently resisted replication. While it is not disputed that the decoy effect exists under certain well-described circumstances, recent failures to replicate earlier studies has induced some scholars to challenge the broader scientific importance of the phenomenon and to question its practical relevance (Frederick et al., 2014; Lynn and Yang, 2014).

Tantalized by this controversy, and inspired by the emphasis of both Huber et al. (2014) and Simonson (2014) on the importance of correct choice set configuration, we have designed a large-scale study that allowed us to investigate how subtle changes in the decoy offer influence its effect, providing an insight into boundary conditions for successful replications. Note that since it is well-known that strong prior preferences for either the target or the competitor might inhibit the effect of introducing a decoy (Huber et al., 2014), our study focusses explicitly on scenarios where it is likely that the choices are constructed.

Specifically, we applied our novel experimental method, which gravitates around an allocation scheme that takes inspiration from the lock-in amplification schemes used in physics (Meade, 1983; Scofield, 1994). This allowed us to explore the entire range of decoy attribute values, enabling us to conclude that the reproducibility issues reported in the literature are likely the result of a suboptimal choice of the initial conditions. Furthermore, and most relevant for the practical applications of a decoy, we show that our approach can sequentially and automatically identify the features of the decoy option that maximize choice reversal, making our method readily applicable in the digital marketplace.

Possible explanations for the decoy effect

Although the literature on the decoy effect has a strong history, there is as of now little agreement on the mechanisms that cause the observed decision reversal. Numerous explanations have been offered, ranging from highly cognitive and effortful to more automatic (Yang, 2013).

Two general categories of plausible mechanisms have been suggested (Wedell and Pettibone, 1996). Value shift-based mechanisms assert that the decoy makes the target seem more attractive, independent of the objective values of either target or competitor (Pettibone and Wedell, 2000). Value added mechanisms on the other hand assert that the decoy makes the target appear the safer choice by raising its value relative to the competitor. An exemplar of the latter is work by Simonson (1989), who demonstrated that a decoy makes it easier for people to justify the choice for the target. However, neither of the mechanisms seems able to fully explain the decoy effect across different moderating conditions. Thus, it is up to future research to provide a more comprehensive explanatory framework (see also the discussion in Yang (2013), or Pettibone and Wedell (2007)). In the current article, however, we do not seek additional explanatory mechanisms, but rather explore the contextual effects of the location of the decoy and practical methods to optimize this location, irrespective of its underlying cause.

The effect of the position of the decoy

The current article focusses on the often discussed yet relatively little-researched explanation for the decoy effect that the probability of the choice reversal is related to the relative positioning of the decoy option on the respective attributes. To illustrate, consider a computer company that wants to increase its market share in the laptop segment against one of its competitors. The company offers a product (the target) that comes with a better battery but less memory than the competing one (the competitor). As neither product is strictly dominant over the other, personal preference will determine the (population average) probability of choosing the target. Let us now imagine that the company that sells the target product introduces a decoy laptop that has the same battery of the target but a less memory. In this situation, it is to be expected that if (for example,) the amount of memory of the decoy is too close to that of the target, the two products may appear as basically identical and the decoy will hardly have an effect on the choice reversal. If on the other hand the amount of memory of the decoy offer is too far from that of the target, potential buyers will not perceive the decoy as a plausible alternative, thereby also rendering the decoy ineffective. Huber et al. (2014) identify such effects of the position of the decoy in attribute space as one of the possible explanations for the recent failures to replicate existing decoy studies.

In this article, we limit ourselves to the most researched type of decoy: asymmetrically dominated decoys. An asymmetrically dominated decoy is defined as an option, which is completely dominated by the target on at least one attribute, and where the decoy itself does not possess an attribute that is superior to the target (Lynn and Yang, 2014). That is, we limit ourselves to a region of the attribute space indicated by the shaded rectangle in Fig. 1, left panel.

Figure 1
figure 1

Illustration of possible sizes of the decoy effect for different decoy positions. Left panel: placement of asymmetrically dominated decoys. Right panel: Positions of range (R), extreme range (R*), frequency (F), and range-frequency decoys (RF).

It is of interest to hypothesize the possible effects of different positions of the decoy in the attribute space depicted in Fig. 1. The decoy literature has, until recently (Trueblood et al., 2014), tended to stay close to the sparse representation as presented in Huber et al. (1982) and the right-hand side of Fig. 1. In this literature, different types of decoys are identified: the range decoy (R) is defined as an option, that is slightly weaker than the target on the target’s weakest attribute: a range decoy increases the range of an attribute dimension on which the competitor is weakest. The frequency decoy (F) refers to an option that increases the frequency of the attribute dimension on which the target is superior. The range-frequency decoy (denoted RF) is a combination of range and frequency manipulations, and the extreme range (R*) decoy represents a more extreme version of the range decoy. Importantly, it is demonstrated in (Huber et al., 1982) that different decoy positions result in different sizes of the effect.

Figure 2 represents our hypothesized target choice probabilities as a function of the decoy location for the laptop scenario. The figure shows that the competitor C scores higher on attribute 2 (the RAM), while the target T has a higher score on attribute 1 (the hours of battery life). Introducing a decoy D, which is asymmetrically dominated by the target, can lead to an increased preference for T compared with D. However, the exact position of the optimal decoy (that is, the position that maximizes the number of choices for T) in this space is unknown. Following Wedell (1991), we hypothesize the effect of the decoy to be first increasing, and then decreasing as the distance between target and decoy passes a threshold value. By superimposing an underlying continuous distribution on the multitude of reported discrete decoy measurements (based on, for example, Huber et al., 1982; Ratneshwar et al., 1987; Simonson, 1989; Tversky and Simonson, 1992; Ariely and Wallsten, 1995; Kivetz et al., 2004; Trueblood et al., 2013) and cross-referencing these with a probability density matrix derived from the Multiattribute Linear Ballistic Accumulator (Trueblood et al., 2014), we constructed Fig. 2. The red dashed vertical line shows different possible placements of the decoy D as a function of attribute 2 for a fixed choice of attribute 1; the left panel of the figure shows the hypothesized probability of choosing the target as a function of attribute 2. The shaded region in the left panel indicates our expectations regarding the effect of the placement of D on the probability of choosing T (dense colour regions=higher probability).

Figure 2
figure 2

Density map (left panel) of the possible effect of decoy location in two dimensional attribute space for the laptop scenario. The right panel shows the expected probablity of choosing the target as a function of the second attribute.

The current study

On the basis of the above analysis of the existing work, we hypothesize that the replication issues reported in recent literature may be because of a suboptimal positioning of the decoy in attribute space. In the current experiment we replicate a number of decoy studies to investigate this hypothesis, but contrary to the original studies we sample from a broad range of attribute values along one of the dimensions. Hence, we can explore the effect of the decoy as a function of its position. Second, to restore the practical applicability of decoy strategies, it is necessary to design a method that can efficiently explore the attribute space and properly position the decoy offer in practical situations. For this purpose, we examine the performance of an algorithm that is routinely used in experimental physics to sequentially position the decoy such that the choice reversal is optimized.

Method

To settle the debate on the reproducibility of the decoy effect, and to establish a method for the optimal positioning of a decoy offer, we ran an experiment in which a total of N=7125 respondents were subjected to five different decoy tasks that have been examined at least twice before in the existing literature. Next to the laptop scenario described above, we included a hotel room scenario with attributes walking distance to destination and price of the room (Simonson, 1989; Lynn and Yang, 2014), the well-known Economist subscription scenario with attributes online, print, or combined subscription and price of the subscription (Ariely, 2008; Lynn and Yang, 2014), a 6-pack of beer scenario with attributes price and quality rating (Huber et al., 1982; Lynn and Yang, 2014), and a frozen orange juice scenario with again a quality rating and price (Ratneshwar et al., 1987; Frederick et al., 2014). Table 1 highlights whether previous replications have been consistent or not. The table further presents the positions of the competitor C, target T, and decoy D options in attribute space (A1 and A2) in the original studies. The * indicates the attribute manipulated in the current study. The indicates that higher values of this attribute correspond to a lower probability of choosing the target.

Table 1 Overview of the five decoy tasks used in this study and their attribute values

A number of respondents (n=506) were confronted with a binary choice task without a decoy option to enable estimation of the probability of choosing the target, denoted p(T). For n=1467 respondents the value of one of the decoy attributes, A 2 ( D ) , was chosen uniformly at random within a reasonable range to enable estimation of the probability p ( T D ) of choosing the target as a function of the position of the decoy. Finally, for two sets of n=2556 and n=2596 respondents the value of A 2 ( D ) was optimized sequentially starting from two different initial values. The sequential allocation was done using an experimentation scheme called lock-in amplification (Kaptein and Iannuzzi, 2015) (see details below), which allowed us to approximate the value of the derivative at a specific point of the (unknown) function relating the attribute value to the probability of selecting the target. Using a gradient ascent method (see, for example, Poggio et al., 2011), we could subsequently update the attribute value to sequentially find the position of the decoy that maximizes target selection. This approach, which is similar to that used in physics to stabilize experimental setups (Meade, 1983; Scofield, 1994), is particularly suitable for decoy positioning in applied settings: compared to random exploration, lock-in amplification is robust to high noise, does not require the specification of a functional form, and has the ability to follow drifting variables (which, in our case, translates to possible drifts in the optimal decoy position over time) (Gaber et al., 2005; Kaptein and Iannuzzi, 2015). Thus, the study was set up such that we could replicate five previously replicated decoy studies, extend them by analyzing the effect of the positioning of the decoy along the full range of one of the attributes, and test a sequential allocation scheme that can be used to position decoy offers in practice.

Participants and procedure

Our participants consisted of 7125 crowd-sourced workers from Amazon Mechanical Turk, each completing a Human Intelligence Task (HIT). In total 7134 participants started the survey, but 9 did not fill out any of the questions and were thus excluded from the analysis. Amazon Mechanical Turk is a popular web service that enables so-called “requesters” to pay individuals known as “workers” a fee on completion of an online task. It has proven a reliable tool for enlisting participants in online social research (Eriksson and Simpson, 2010; Horton and Chilton, 2010; Ipeirotis et al., 2010; Paolacci et al., 2010; Buhrmester et al., 2011; Mason and Suri, 2012). MTurks built-in system of qualifications was used to ensure that mainly US-based workers with a HIT approval rate of at least 90% and at least 100+ submitted prior HITS could participate, guaranteeing the quality of the collected data.

We implemented our study by embedding a custom survey platform within the MTurk worker interface. The attribute values of the decoy options in the sequential allocation conditions were dynamically updated using StreamingBandit server running the lock-in feedback algorithm (see below for details of the algorithm) (Kaptein and Iannuzzi, 2015; Kaptein and Kruijswijk, 2016). Hence, in the two sequential optimization conditions—which differed only in their initial starting point—the positioning of the decoy was updated sequentially such as to converge to a position in attribute space that would maximize the probability of choosing the target. Note that the order of the options (target, competition and decoy) within each scenario was randomized for each participant to control for possible effects of the ordering of the options. In each condition the HIT consisted of an initial page requesting informed consent followed by the decoy scenarios and a short closing survey querying the country of residence, gender, age, and education of respondents. As a reimbursement, the participants received a payment of US$0.40 through their Amazon Mechanical Turk account. All resulting datasets have been made publicly available in the Dataverse repository (van Emden et al. 2016).

Of our participants, 46.4% were female. The majority of our participants were between 25 and 44 years of age (65.3%), and resided in the United States (99.2%). Over 90% completed a high school (or higher) education.

Materials

Figure 3 displays a screenshot, including the exact text, of the laptop scenario as used in this study. The exact descriptions used for the other four scenarios are as follows:

  1. 1

    (Hotel) “You’re going to have a job interview out of town and will need to book a hotel room for the trip. you will not be reimbursed for the hotel room. You find the following deals online, which one would you choose?”

    D: Hotel W: 40 min away from the interview site. $119/nt.

    C: Hotel J: 5 min away from the interview site. $179/nt.

    T: Hotel N: 15 min away from the interview site. $129/nt.

  2. 2

    (Economist) “Welcome to the Economist Subscription Centre. Pick the type of subscription you want to buy or renew”:

    C: Economist.com subscription—$56.95.

    D: Print subscription—$143.90.

    T: Print & Web subscription—$125.00.

  3. 3

    (Beer) “If you had to choose one of the following brand of beer to purchase, which one would it be? Average Quality Rating Scale: (100=Best, 0=Worst)”

    D: Price / sixpack: $7.80—Average Quality Rating: 30

    C: Price / sixpack: $8.60—Average Quality Rating: 70

    T: Price / sixpack: $7.80—Average Quality Rating: 50

  4. 4

    (Juice) “Below you will find some brands of frozen concentrated orange juice. You know only the price and the quality ratings made by consumer reports. Given that you had to buy one brand based on this information alone, which one would it be? In case of the quality rating, 100=ideal.”

    D: Brand W: Price per can $1.15. Quality rating 30

    T: Brand N: Price per can $1.20. Quality rating 50

    C: Brand J: Price per can $2.00. Quality rating 70

Figure 3
figure 3

Screenshot of the laptop decoy scenario as used in this study.

The lock-in amplification algorithm

Here we detail the idea of lock-in amplification in continuous time. Let’s assume that y, the probability of choosing the decoy, is a continuous function of x: y=f(x) (in our case, p ( T D ) =f( A 2 )). Let’s further assume that x oscillates with time according to:

(1) x ( t ) = x 0 + A c o s ( ω t )

where ω is the angular frequency of the oscillation, x0 its central value, and A its amplitude. For relatively small values of A, Taylor expanding f(x) around x0 to the second order, one obtains:

(2) y ( x ( t ) ) = f ( x 0 ) + ( x 0 x 0 A c o s ( ω t ) ) ( f x | x = x 0 ) + 1 2 ( x 0 x 0 A c o s ( ω t ) ) 2 ( 2 f x 2 | x = x 0 )

which can be simplified to:

(3) y ( x ( t ) ) = k A c o s ( ω t ) ( f x | x = x 0 ) + 1 4 A 2 c o s ( 2 ω t ) ( 2 f x 2 | x = x 0 )

where k=f( x 0 )+1/4( 2 f/ x 2 | x = x 0 ). Thus, for small oscillations y becomes the sum of three terms: a constant term, a term oscillating at angular frequency ω, and a term oscillating at angular frequency 2ω.

Suppose we can actively manipulate x and measure y, and that f is continuous and only has one maximum and no minimum. Further suppose we are interesting in finding x m a x =arg m a x x f(x) and that our measurements contain noise:

(4) y ( t ) = f ( x ( t ) ) + ε

where ε denotes the noise and επ(), where π is some probability density function and E[ε|x]=0. In physical lock-in amplifiers (Scofield, 1994), one multiplies the observed y variable by cos(ωt). Using equation (3) and equation (4), we obtain:

(5) y ω ( t ) = c o s ( ω t ) [ k A c o s ( ω t ) ( f x | x = x 0 ) + 1 4 A 2 c o s ( 2 ω t ) ( 2 f x 2 | x = x 0 ) + ε ]

where yω is the value of y after it has been multiplied by cos(ωt). This can be written more compactly as:

(6) y ω = A 2 ( f x | x = x 0 ) + k ω c o s ( ω t ) + k 2 ω c o s ( 2 ω t ) + k 3 ω c o s ( 3 ω t ) + ε cos ( ω t )

where

(7) k ω = k + A 2 /8 ( 2 f x 2 | x = x 0 ) ,
(8) k 2 ω = A /2 ( 2 f x 2 | x = x 0 ) ,
(9) k 3 ω = A 2 /8 ( 2 f x 2 | x = x 0 ) .

Integrating yω over a time T=(2πN)/(ω), where N is a positive integer and T denotes the time needed to integrate N full oscillations, one obtains:

(10) y ω * = T A 2 ( f x | x = x 0 ) + 0 T ε c o s ( ω t )

Depending on the noise level, one can tailor the integration time, T, in such a way to reduce the second addendum of the right hand of equation (10) to negligible levels, effectively averaging out the noise in the measurements. Under these circumstances, y ω * provides a direct measurement of the value of the first derivative of f at x=x0. This provides a logical update strategy for x0: if y ω * <0, then x0 is larger than the value of x that maximizes f; likewise, if y ω * >0, x0 is smaller than the value of x that maximizes f. Thus, based on the oscillation observed in yω we are now able to move x0 closer to x=arg m a x x f(x) using an update rule x 0 := x 0 +γ y ω * , where γ quantifies the learn rate of the procedure (Kaptein and Iannuzzi, 2015). Note that the lock-in amplification algorithm depends on a starting value, x0, an amplitude A, a learn-rate γ, and an integration time T. The exact values as used in the experiment are presented in Table 2. Also, the actual discrete algorithm used in the studies is described in the Supplementary Materials.

Table 2 Values of the tuning parameters of the lock-in amplification algorithm as used in the experiment

Ethics committee psychology (CEP) approval

The Psychology Research Ethics Committee (in Dutch: “Commissie Ethiek Psychologie”, CEP) considers applications for ethical approval for research conducted within the Institute of Psychology of Leiden University, the Netherlands. The Psychology Ethics Committee has reviewed and approved the current research under the title of “Decoy Amazon Mechnical Turk Study—2016”. CEP code: CEP16-0203/42. Contact ethiekpsychologie@fsw.leidenuniv.nl for more information.

Results

In this section, we describe the results of our experiment. First, we detail how we estimate, based on the data, the quantities of interest (for example, p ˆ T , p ˆ T D , and p ˆ T D ( A 2 )). Subsequently, we present the results and discuss both the effects of the positioning of the decoy on the probability of selecting the target, as well as the performance of the lock-in amplification algorithm to sequentially position the decoy. Note that the main results are presented in Fig. 4, which shows the estimated probability of selecting the target when the decoy is absent, p ˆ ( T ) , the probability of selecting the target when the decoy is present as a function of its position, p ˆ ( T D ) , the values of C and T on the second attribute, and the optimal position of the decoy, p m a x ( T D ) , as uncovered by lock-in feedback. Also, the figure shows the convergence path(s) of the lock-in feedback for each scenario using two different starting points in the horizontal lower panels.

Figure 4
figure 4

Results of our decoy experiment. Displayed are the estimated probabilities of selecting the target as a function of attribute 2 for different conditions and their credible intervals.

Estimation procedure

Before discussing the results, we first detail our (Bayesian) estimation procedure for both p ˆ T and p ˆ T D ( A 2 ) as presented in Fig. 4. To estimate p ˆ T we assume the observed number of choices for the target to follow a binomial distribution with parameters θ, n=s+f, where the former is the probability of a success and the latter the total number of trials (here we exclude, as is standard in the decoy literature, trials in which the decoy itself was selected (Lynn and Yang, 2014)). We use s to refer to the number of times the target was selected, f the number of times the competitor was selected, and n the total number of available observations in this condition. We thus have a binomial sampling distribution:

p ( s | θ , n ) = n ! s ! ( n s ) ! θ s ( 1 θ ) n s =Binom ( θ , n ) .

Next, we use a fairly uninformative, uniform priorFootnote 1 on θ:

p(θ|α,β)=Unif[0,1]=Beta(α=1,β=1)= 1 B ( α , β ) θ α 1 (1 θ ) β 1

where B() is the Beta function (for example, Wilcox, 1981). We obtain the posterior:

p(θ|s,n,α,β)= p ( s | θ , n ) p ( θ | α , β ) p ( s | n , α , β ) =Beta(α=s+1,β=f+1)

(see, for example, Gelman et al., 2013, for a derivation)). The estimates of p ˆ T presented in Fig. 4 are the 2.5th percentile, the expected value, and the 97.5th percentile of this posterior distribution of θ.

For the estimation of p ˆ T D ( A 2 ) we assume that each individual observation yi{0,1} (where i =1 n y i =s) is sampled from a Bernoulli(θ), and θ depends on the value of A2 via a standard probit link

(11) θ = Φ ( β 0 + β 1 A 2 + β 2 A 2 2 + + β k A 2 k )

where Φ() is the standard normal CDF. We examined different orders k of the polynomial (appropriately centring the data): Fig. 4 shows the results for k=4, at which point increasing k does not seem to visually improve model fit. Using the data augmentation scheme as described in Albert and Chib (1993), and implemented in MCMCpack (Martin et al., 2011), we obtain m=10000 draws from the posterior distribution p(β|y,A2) using an improper flat prior for β: p(β) 1. Given the m draws of β, we obtain m draws from the posterior predictive distribution p( θ ˜ |β,y, A 2 ) for each of 100 values of A2 spaced equally within the ranges displayed in Fig. 4 for each scenario. The figure presents the 2.5th percentile of these draws, their mean, and the 97.5th percentile.

Explaining the replication failures: the positioning of the decoy

Figure 4 shows the results for each of the five scenarios. Our results readily provide an explanation for the reason why the laptop scenario has been inconsistent in prior replications: the position of the decoy in the original studies (the vertical dashed line labelled A 2 o r i g ) is such that the probability of choosing the target in the absence or in the presence of the decoy is too close to trigger a noticeable decision reversal. Hence, while the effect has been observed in the initial study it is no surprise that it was relatively small and inconsistent. Our data however also shows that, for smaller values of A 2 ( D ) , the difference between the offers becomes sufficiently large to generate a clear decoy effect.

For the hotel and the Economist scenarios—which also previously failed to replicate—a similar pattern emerges: The original decoy was positioned such that the effects were small. In both cases, however, it is clear that larger effects can be obtained by moving the decoy to higher values of the attribute. Especially the Economist scenario seems to be ill-positioned in the original studies and, while this scenario potentially provides a convincing demonstration of the effect, its replication failure under the initial context is not surprising. The hotel scenario was also presumably not replicated in the previous literature because of a poorly chosen decoy position, as it seems that only much higher values on A 2 ( D ) may potentially demonstrate a decoy effect. For the beer and the juice scenarios, which have been replicated consistently, the original positioning of the decoy was such that the effects were relatively large, and hence were easily replicated. Although in neither case the decoy seems to be positioned at its absolute maximum, the effects are large enough that it is no surprise that these scenarios provided consistent results in previous studies.

Finding optimal decoy values in practice: lock-in feedback

Next to highlighting the contextual effects that caused previous replication failures, it is clear from the top panel in Fig. 4 that the lock-in amplification scheme is able to sequentially bring the decoy offer towards the position where the effect is maximized—an extremely important feature from both a practical and a methodological perspective. Hence, next to demonstrating why a number of replications might have failed, the current study demonstrates a readily usable method to introduce and position decoy offers in practice. Clearly, in all of the scenarios, the effect of the decoy could have been demonstrated more strongly if the selection of the decoy attributes had been guided by a lock-in feedback.

Discussion

The fact that the decoy effect has occasionally resisted replication has led some to refrain from using decoys in practice, and even question the scientific importance of the phenomenon (Frederick et al., 2014). Our study, however, confirms that subtle changes in decoy position are of great importance for the strength of the effect, supporting the emphasis of both Huber et al. (2014) and Simonson (2014) on the context-dependence of choice behaviour and the significance of correct choice set configuration. This result also supports the initial identification of Huber et al. (1982) of a limited area in attribute space for which the decoy effect occurs.

By not only demonstrating the effect of the positioning of a decoy offer, but also providing a method to “lock into” an optimal decoy position, we present future researchers the option to pin down this, and potentially other, quantifiable aspects of online choice behaviour. It seems to us to be of great practical and scientific use to be able to determine optimal stimuli positions sequentially, with the potential to isolate other contextual influences as the optimal stimuli positions might drift over time. Our proposed method is thus of relevance for future studies into the decoy effect and beyond.

Furthermore, although it has been suggested that decoys are hard to use in practice (Huber et al., 2014), our sequential optimization method reaffirms its potential use in digital marketing practice. In contrast to offline stores, online shops do not need to produce decoy goods to make use of the effect. They can offer clear numeric, easily optimizable representations of any two product dimensions, such as a price and a quality rating. As such, we expect self-optimizing decoys to be a valuable addition to online dynamic pricing technology (for example, Kannan and Kopalle, 2001; Jiang et al., 2011) and recommender systems (Teppan and Felfernig, 2012). As can be deducted from experiments such as our beer scenario, a correctly positioned online decoy can change a target’s choice share by multiple percentage points—an impressive feat. We also see ample room for further research, for example by extending our work to broader human decision making related paradigms such as Multi-Attribute Utility Theory-based modelling (Von Winterfeldt and Edwards, 1986; Felfernig et al., 2008).

To conclude, we have shown that failures to replicate the decoy effect in certain scenarios are likely due to a suboptimal position of the decoy offer in attribute space. Furthermore, we demonstrated that sequential optimization methods borrowed from physics can ensure a correct decoy position. It is reasonable to assume that similar algorithms will soon be used to address other open issues in the social sciences in both theoretical analysis and practical applications.

Data availability

The source code, the scripts used to generate the statistics, the estimation scripts and the datasets analyzed in the current study are available in the Dataverse repository: http://doi:10.7910/DVN/FCHU0J.

Additional information

How to cite this article: Kaptein MC, van Emden R and Iannuzzi D (2016) Tracking the decoy: maximizing the decoy effect through sequential experimentation. Palgrave Communications. 2:16082 doi: 10.1057/palcomms.2016.82.Footnote 2