Skip to main content
Log in

Market Segmentation and the Location of Production Activities

  • Symposium Article
  • Published:
Comparative Economic Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines whether local protection has hindered China's market integration process using a firm-level data set. Our empirical results show that an industry's geographic concentration level is negatively correlated with its labour productivity while its concentration at plant level is not. Since labour productivity is strongly positively correlated with an industry's profitability, this evidence supports Bai et al.'s (2004) argument that local government has a stronger incentive to protect highly profitable industries. We also find that a province's market shares of its protected industries grow faster than other industries, which also supports the argument that local protection slows down China's market integration process.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This idea is first proposed by Bai et al. (2004).

  2. Because Σ p  Δs pit ≡0, Σ p (y pit y pt )≡0, Σ p  Δs pt ≡0, we have α0≡0.

  3. Ellison and Glaeser (1997) consider industries with γ<0.02 as ‘not very localised’ and these with γ>0.05 as ‘very localised’.

  4. The Hausman test cannot reject the hypothesis that the estimates of the random-effect model are consistent at any conventional statistical level.

References

  • Bai, C-E, Du, Y, Tao, Z and Tong, SY . 2004: Local protectionism and regional specialization: Evidence from China's industries. Journal of International Economics 63 (2): 397–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bain, JS . 1951: Relation of profit rate to industry concentration: American manufacturing, 1936–1940. Quarterly Journal of Economics 65 (3): 293–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, JA and Penn, DW . 1976: The concentration–profitability relationship: Is there a critical concentration ratio? Journal of Industrial Economics 25 (2): 133–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dumais, G, Ellison, G and Glaeser, EL . 2002: Geographic concentration as a dynamic process. Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (2): 193–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, G and Glaeser, EL . 1997: Geographic concentration in US manufacturing industries: A dartboard approach. Journal of Political Economy 105 (5): 889–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, A . 1994: China: internal market development and regulation. World Bank Publications: Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Naughton, B . 2003: How much can regional integration do to unify China's markets? In: Hope, NC, Yang, DT, Yang, ML and Li, MY (eds). How Far Across the River? Chinese Policy Reform at the Millennium, Chapter 8, pp. 204–232. Stanford University Press: Stanford, CA.

  • Park, A, Jin, H, Rozelle, S and Huang, J . 2002: Market emergence and transition: Arbitrage, transaction costs, and autarky in China's grain markets. American Journal of Agricultural 84 (1): 67–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poncet, S . 2003: Measuring Chinese domestic and international integration. China Economic Review 14 (1): 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poncet, S . 2005: A fragmented China: Measure and determinants of Chinese domestic market disintegration. Review of International Economics 13 (3): 409–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, A . 2000: The razor's edge: Distortions and incremental reform in the People's Republic of China. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (4): 1091–1135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, X and Tan, K . 2007: Incremental reform and distortions in China's product and factor markets. World Bank Economic Review 21 (2): 279–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix: Variable definitions

Appendix: Variable definitions

  1. 1)

    Labour productivity of industry i is defined as,

    where y j is the value added of firm j in industry i, and e j is the number of employees of firm j.

  2. 2)

    Labour productivity of industry i in province p is defined as,

    where y j is the value added of firm j in industry i of province p and e j is the number of employees of firm j.

  3. 3)

    The standard deviation of labour productivity of industry i is defined as

    where P is the number of provinces.

  4. 4)

    The market share of province p is defined as,

    where q is the sales of firm j.

  5. 5)

    The market share of province p in industry i is defined as,

    where q is the sales of firm j.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Liu, H., Tong, S. Market Segmentation and the Location of Production Activities. Comp Econ Stud 51, 302–322 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2008.49

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2008.49

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation