Skip to main content
Log in

Institutional Resilience and Economic Systems: Lessons from Elinor Ostrom’s Work

  • Article
  • Published:
Comparative Economic Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Comparative economic systems literature deals extensively with ‘systemic functions’ and ‘performance criteria’ such as growth, efficiency and equity but rarely mentions the topic of resilience. This paper focusses on the issue of resilience while drawing several important lessons from the contributions in this respect of 2009 Nobel Prize in Economics co-recipient, Elinor Ostrom: The effects of alternative institutional arrangements and social norms as a source of both resilience and vulnerability; the problem of ‘highly optimized tolerance’ to specific sources of uncertainty; polycentricity as a possible structural solution to sustainability problems. A key point is that resilience is more than mere ‘absorptive capacity’ or ‘speed of recovery’: it depends on innovation and creative socio-cultural adaptations made possible by flexible and polycentric institutional processes. That has important implications for the ways we define and assess institutional performance and institutional design.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Adger, WN . 2000: Social and ecological resilience: Are they related? Progress in Human Geography 24 (3): 347–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adger, WN . 2006: Vulnerability. Global Environmental Change 16 (3): 268–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, AA and Demsetz, H . 1972: Production, information costs, and economic organization. The American Economic Review 62 (5): 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aligica, PD and Tarko, V . 2012: Polycentricity: From Polanyi to Ostrom, and beyond. Governance 25 (2): 237–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aligica, PD and Tarko, V . 2013: Co-Production, polycentricity and value heterogeneity: The Ostroms’ public choice institutionalism revisited. American Political Science Review 107 (4), doi:10.1017/S0003055413000427.

  • Axtell, R . 2003: Economics as distributed computation. In: Terano, T, Deguchi, H and Takadama, K (eds). Meeting the Challenge of Social Problems via Agent-based Simulation. Berlin and New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bak, P . 1996: How Nature Works: The Science of Self-organized Criticality. New York: Copernicus.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Berkes, F and Folke, C (eds). 1998: Linking social and ecological systems: Management practices and social mechanisms for building resilience. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berkes, F, Colding, J and Folke, C (eds). 2003: Navigating social–ecological systems: Building resilience for complexity and change. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bicchieri, C . 2005: The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, PJ (ed). 1996 [2001]: Why culture matters: Economics, politics, and the imprint of history. In: Calculation and Coordination. Routledge: New York, pp. 248–265.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bornstein, M . 1994: Comparative economic systems: Models and cases, 7th Edition. Boston: Irwin, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, JM and Tullock, G . 1962/1999: The calculus of consent. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, JM and Congleton, RD . 1998: Politics by principle, not interest: Toward nondiscriminatory democracy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, JM . 1999: Order defined in the process of its emergence. In: The Logical Foundations of Constitutional Liberty. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlson, JM and Doyle, J . 1999: Highly optimized tolerance: A mechanism for power laws in designed systems. Physical Review E 60 (2): 1412–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson, JM and Doyle, J . 2002: Complexity and robustness. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 99 (1): 2538–2545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, SR, Walker, B, Anderies, J and Abel, N . 2001: From metaphor to measurement: Resilience of what to what? Ecosystems 4 (8): 765–781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costanza, R, Bobbi, Low, Ostrom, E and Wilson, J . 2001: Institutions, ecosystems, and sustainability. New York: Lewis Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamlee‐Wright, E and Storr, VH . 2009a: ‘There’s no place like New Orleans’: Sense of place and community recovery in the ninth ward after Hurricane Katrina. Journal of Urban Affairs 31 (5): 615–634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamlee-Wright, Emily and Storr, VH . 2009b: Club goods and post-disaster community return. Rationality and Society 21 (4): 429–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamlee-Wright, E and Storr, VH . 2010a: The role of social entrepreneurship in post-Katrina community recovery. International Journal of Innovation and Regional Development 2 (1): 149–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamlee-Wright, E and Storr, VH (eds). 2010b: The political economy of hurricane Katrina and community rebound. Cheltenham, UK and Northhampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chakrabarti, A . 2011: Transhumance, livelihood and sustainable development and conflict between formal institution and communal governance: An evaluative note on East Himalayan state of Sikkim, India. In: International Conference on Social Science and Humanity IPEDR, Vol. 5. IACSIT Press: Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Committee on the Human Dimensions of Global Change, National Research Council; Ostrom, E, Dietz, T, Dolsak, N, Stern, P, Stonich, S and Weber, EU . 2002: The drama of commons. National Academies Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, S and Ostrom, E . 1995: A grammar of institutions. American Political Science Review 89 (3): 582–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, J . 2005: Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Folke, C . 2006: Resilience: The emergence of a perspective for social–ecological systems analyses. Global Environmental Change 16 (3): 253–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, C, McKeen, M and Ostrom, E . 2000: People and forests. Communities, institutions, and governance politics, science, and the environment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giugni, M, McAdam, D. and Tilly, C (eds). 1999: How social movements matter. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gregory, PR and Stuart, RC . 1999a: Comparative economic systems, 6th Edition. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gregory, PR and Stuart, RC . 1999b: Comparative economic systems. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunderson, L . 2000: Ecological resilience: In theory and application. Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics 31: 425–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, FA . 1945: Use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review 35 (4): 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, FA . 1967: The result of human action, but not of human design. In: Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics. London: Routledge and Kegan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holling, CS, Schindler, DW, Walker, B and Roughgarden, J . 1995: Biodiversity in the functioning of ecosystems: An ecological synthesis. In: Perring, C, Mäle, K-G, Folke, C, Holling, CS and Jansson, B-O (eds). Biodiversity Loss: Economic and Ecological Issues. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press pp. 44–83.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, M, Anderies, J and Ostrom, E . 2004: A framework to analyze the robustness of social-ecological systems from an institutional perspective. Ecology and Society 9 (1): 18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, M, Anderies, J and Ostrom, E . 2007: Robustness of social-ecological systems to spatial and temporal variability. Society and Natural Resources 20 (4): 307–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, MA and Anderies, JM . 2013: A multi-method approach to study robustness of social-ecological systems: The case of small-scale irrigation systems. Journal of Institutional Economics 9 (4): 427–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, H . 2009: In: Aligica, PD and Weinstein, KR (eds). The Essential Herman Kahn: In Defense of Thinking. Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kasper, W, Streit, ME and Boettke, PJ . 2012: Institutional economics: Property, competition, policies, 2nd Edition. Cheltenham, UK and Northhampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerekes, CB and Williamson, CR . 2008: Unveiling de Soto’s mystery: Property rights, capital formation, and development. Journal of Institutional Economics 4 (3): 299–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kling, A and Schulz, N . 2009: From poverty to prosperity: Intangible assets, hidden liabilities and the lasting triumph over scarcity. New York: Encounter Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lansing, JS . 1991: Priests and programmers: Technologies of power in the engineered landscape of Bali. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lansing, JS and Kremer, JN . 1993: Emergent properties of Balinese water temples. American Anthropologist 95 (1): 97–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lansing, JS . 2012: Perfect order: Recognizing complexity in Bali. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, PT . 2011: Government, Clubs, and Constitutions. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 80 (2): 301–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, PT and Boettke, PJ . 2009: Two-tiered entrepreneurship and economic development. International Review of Law and Economics 29 (3): 252–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lovett, RA . 2010: Why Chile fared better than Haiti. Nature (1 March), http://www.nature.com/news/2010/100301/full/news.2010.100.html.

  • Mandelbrot, B and Hudson, R . 2004: The (Mis)behavior of markets: A fractal view of risk, ruin, and reward. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAdam, D, Tarrow, S and Tilly, C . 2001: Dynamics of contention. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, JH and Page, SE . 2007: Complex adaptive systems: An introduction to computational models of social life. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, DC . 1991: Institutions. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 97–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, DC . 1994: Economic performance through time. The American Economic Review 84 (3): 359–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Driscoll, GP . 1977: Economics as a coordination problem: The contributions of Friedrich A. Hayek. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel, Inc, Available online from Library of Economics and Liberty (2013), http://www.econlib.org/library/NPDBooks/ODriscoll/odrCP.html.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M . 1982: The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E . 1990: Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E . 1994: Neither market nor state: Governance of common-pool resources in the twenty first century. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E . 1999: Polycentricity, complexity, and the commons. The Good Society 9 (2): 37–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E . 2005: Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E . 2008: Developing a method for analyzing institutional change. In: Batie, S and Mercuro, N (eds). Alternative Institutional Structures: Evolution and Impact. London, UK: Routledge pp. 48–76.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V . 1991: The meaning of American federalism: Constituting a self-governing society. ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E and Hess, C . 2007: Understanding knowledge as a commons: From theory to practice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E and Ostrom, V . 2004: The quest for meaning in public choice. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 63 (1): 105–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E, Schroeder, L and Wynne, S . 2003: Analyzing the performance of alternative institutional arrangements for sustaining rural infrastructure in developing countries. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 3 (1): 11–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E, Gardner, R and Walker, J . 1994: Rules, games and common-pool resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Parks, RB, Baker, PC, Larry, LK, Oakerson, RJ, Ostrom, E, Ostrom, V, Percy, SL, Vandivort, MB, Whitaker, GP and Wilson, RK . 1981: Consumers as coproducers of public services: Some economic and institutional considerations. Policy Studies Journal 9 (7): 1001–1011.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pryor, FL . 2005: A guidebook to the comparative study of economic systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reisman, G . 1996: Capitalism: A treatise on economics. Ottawa, IL: Jameson Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridley, M . 1996: The origins of virtue: Human instincts and the evolution of cooperation. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. (ed). 1995: The state of humanity. Oxford, UK and Cambridge, MA: Blackwell in Association with the Cato Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J . 1998: The ultimate resource 2. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sowell, T . 2002: A conflict of visions: Ideological origins of political struggles. Cambridge, MA: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tainter, JA . 1988: The collapse of complex societies. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C . 1993: European revolutions: 1492–1992. Oxford, UK and Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. and Wood, L . 2009: Social movements, 1768–2008 2nd Edition. Boulder, London: Paradigm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Valen, L . 1973: A new evolutionary law. Evolutionary Theory 1: 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker, B, Holling, CS, Carpenter, S and Kinzig, A . 2004: Resilience, adaptability and transformability in social–ecological systems. Ecology and Society 9 (2): 5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B . 1995: The economic role of political Institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 11 (1): 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, CR . 2010: The two sides of deSoto: Property rights, land titling, and development. In: Emily, C-W (ed). The Annual Proceeding of the Wealth and Well-being of Nations, 2009–2010 Volume 2 Beloit College Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, OE . 2000: The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature 38 (3): 595–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, DS, Ostrom, E and Cox, M . 2013: Generalizing the core design principles for the efficacy of groups. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 90 (Supplement): S21–S32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Aligica, P., Tarko, V. Institutional Resilience and Economic Systems: Lessons from Elinor Ostrom’s Work. Comp Econ Stud 56, 52–76 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2013.29

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2013.29

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation