Skip to main content
Log in

Multidivisional vs metanational governance of the multinational enterprise

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The effective and efficient management of diversified business firms that supply multiple products and operate in multiple, dynamic markets, especially large multinational enterprises (MNEs), builds upon a number of specific governance principles. These governance principles allow the alignment of environmental characteristics, strategy and organization. Given the rising need to “learn from the world”, Doz et al., in their influential Harvard Business School Press book entitled From Global to Metanational, have proposed a new set of governance principles described under the “metanational” umbrella concept. This paper revisits the metanational, using a comparative institutional perspective; here we contrast multidivisional and metanational governance principles. A comparative institutional analysis suggests that the metanational's application potential in terms of actually improving the effectiveness and efficiency of MNE governance may be subject to more qualification than suggested by Doz et al. Senior MNE management must therefore reflect carefully before substituting metanational governance principles for the more conventional, multidivisional ones with established contributions to managerial effectiveness and efficiency.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Argyres, N., & Liebeskind, J. P. 1999. Contractual commitments, bargaining power, and governance inseparability: Introducing history into transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 24 (1): 49–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. 1974. The limits of organization. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartlett, C. A. 1986. Building and managing the transnational: The new organizational challenge. In M. E. Porter (Ed.), Competition in global industries: 367–401. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartlett, C. A., & Ghoshal, S. 1989. Managing across borders: The transnational solution. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhidé, A. V. 2000. The origin and evolution of new businesses. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birkinshaw, J. 2000. Entrepreneurship in the global firm. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birkinshaw, J., & Hood, N. 2001. Unleash innovation in foreign subsidiaries. Harvard Business Review, 79 (3): 131–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. 1976. The future of the multinational enterprise. London: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. 2007. Edith Penrose's theory of the growth of the firm and the strategic management of multinational enterprises. Management International Review, 47 (2): 151–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burgelman, R. A. 1983. A model of the interaction of strategic behavior, corporate context, and the concept of strategy. Academy of Management Review, 8 (1): 61–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A., Birkinshaw, J., Morrison, A., & van Basten Batenburg, R. 2003. The future of corporate venturing. MIT Sloan Management Review, 45 (1): 30–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J. A. 1989. Technological innovation and multinational corporations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J. A. 1995. The globalisation of technology: What remains of the product cycle model? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19 (1): 155–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J. A., Dunning, J. H., & Janna, O. E. M. 2004a. Toward a technology-seeking explanation of US direct investment in the United Kingdom. Journal of International Management, 10 (1): 5–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J. A., Gambardella, A., & Granstrand, O. (Eds) 2004b. The economics and management of technological diversification. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J. A., & Iammarino, S. 2000. Multinational corporations and the location of technological innovation in the UK regions. Regional Studies, 34 (4): 317–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J. A., & Piscitello, L. 1999. The emergence of corporate international networks for the accumulation of dispersed technological capabilities. Management International Review, 39 (Special Issue 1): 123–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casadesus-Masanell, R., & Spulber, D. F. 2000. The fable of Fisher Body. Journal of Law and Economics, 43 (1): 67–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A. D. 1998. Strategy and structure. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press paperback edition 20th printing (1st ed. 1962).

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, C. M. 1997. The innovator's dilemma: When new technologies cause great firms to fail. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, 4 (16): 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doz, Y., & Prahalad, C. K. 1993. Managing DMNCs: A search for a new paradigm. In S. Ghosha and D. E. Westney (Eds), Organization theory and the multinational corporation: 24–50. London: Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Doz, Y., Santos, J., & Williamson, P. 2001. From global to metanational: How companies win in the knowledge economy. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenmann, T. R., & Bower, J. L. 2000. The entrepreneurial M-form: Strategic integration in global media firms. Organization Science, 11 (3): 348–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fouraker, L. E., & Stopford, J. M. 1968. Organizational structure and the multinational strategy. Administrative Science Quarterly, 13 (1): 47–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franko, L. G. 1976. The European multinationals: A renewed challenge to American and European big business. Stamford, CT: Greylock.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghemawat, P. 2001. Distance still matters: The hard reality of global expansion. Harvard Business Review, 79 (8): 137–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal, S., & Moran, P. 1996. Theories of economic organization: The case for realism and balance. Academy of Management Review, 21 (1): 58–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal, S., & Westney, D. E. 1993. Introduction and overview. In S. Ghoshal and D. E. Westney (Eds), Organization theory and the multinational corporation: 1–23. London: Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hedlund, G. 1986. The hypermodern MNC: A heterarchy? Human Resource Management, 25 (1): 9–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennart, J. F. 1982. A theory of multinational enterprise. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hennart, J. F. 1991. Control in multinational firms: The role of price and hierarchy. Management International Review, 31 (Special Issue): 71–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill, C. W. L. 1985. Oliver Williamson and the M-form firm: A critical review. Journal of Economic Issues, 19 (3): 731–751.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., & Ireland, R. D. 1990. Mergers and acquisitions and managerial commitment to innovation. Strategic Management Journal, 11 (Summer Special Issue): 29–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, A. Y., & Peeters, C. 2006. Offshoring work: Business hype or the onset of fundamental transformation? Long Range Planning, 39 (3): 221–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, A. Y., Massini, S., & Peeters, C. 2007. From offshoring to globalization of human capital. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Academy of International Business, Indianapolis, Indiana.

  • McGrath, R. G., MacMillan, I. C., & Venkataraman, S. 1995. Defining and developing competence: A strategic process paradigm. Strategic Management Journal, 16 (4): 251–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nocera, J. 2007. Jeff Immelt: GE's model of a modern CEO. International Herald Tribune, 9–10 June: 11, 14.

  • Ohmae, K. 1985. Triad power. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, E. T. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prahalad, C. K., & Doz, Y. 1987. The multinational mission: Balancing local demands and global vision. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricciuti, M. 2004. Gates goes to college. CNET News.com, 1 March.

  • Rugman, A. M. 1981. Inside the multinationals: The economics of internal markets. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M. 2005. The regional multinationals. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2001. Subsidiary specific advantages in multinational enterprises. Strategic Management Journal, 22 (3): 819–834.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2002. Edith Penrose's contribution to the resource-based view of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 23 (8): 769–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2003. Extending the theory of the multinational enterprise: Internalization and strategic management perspectives. Journal of International Business Studies, 34 (2): 125–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2004. A perspective on regional and global strategies of multinational enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies, 35 (1): 3–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2005a. Towards a theory of regional multinationals: A transaction costs economics approach. Management International Review, 45 (Special Issue 1): 5–17.

  • Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2005b. Analysis of multinational strategic management. Cheltenham (UK) and Northhampton (USA): Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2007. Liabilities of regional foreignness and the use of firm-level vs country-level data: A response to Dunning et al. Journal of International Business Studies, 38 (1): 200–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. 1934. The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shanley, M. 1996. Straw men and M-form myths: Comment on Freeland. The American Journal of Sociology, 102 (2): 527–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, R., Siegel, E., & MacMillan, I. C. 1988. Corporate venture capitalists: Autonomy, obstacles and performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 3 (3): 233–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. 1957. Administrative theory: A study of decision-making processes in administrative organization (2nd ed.). New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steel, P., & König, C. J. 2006. Integrating theories of motivation. Academy of Management Review, 31 (4): 889–913.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stopford, J. M., & Wells, L. T. 1972. Managing the multinational enterprise: Organization of the firm and ownership of the subsidiaries. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tallman, S., & Li, J. 1996. Effects of international diversity and product diversity on the performance of multinational firms. Academy of Management Journal, 39 (1): 179–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbeke, A., & Yuan, W. 2007. Entrepreneurship in multinational enterprises: A Penrosean perspective. Management International Review, 47 (2): 241–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vernon, R. 1966. International investment and international trade in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80 (2): 190–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, R. E., & Poynter, T. A. 1990. Organizing for worldwide advantage. In C. A. Bartlett, Y. Doz and G. Hedlund (Eds), Managing the Global Firm: 95–116. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whittington, R., & Mayer, M. 2000. The European corporation: Strategy, structure, and social science. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1971. Managerial discretion, organization form, and the multi-division hypothesis. In R. Marris and A. Wood (Eds), The corporate economy, growth, competition and innovative potential: 343–386. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1996. The mechanisms of governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are indebted to JIBS editor Arie Y. Lewin for his inspiring support, and to two anonymous JIBS reviewers. Their insights greatly increased the quality of the original manuscript. The authors are also grateful to Paul Brugman, Ayesha Malhotra, Sarah Vanden Bussche and Wenlong Yuan for thoughtful comments on earlier drafts.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alain Verbeke.

Additional information

Accepted by Arie Y Lewin, Editor-in-Chief, 25 May 2007. This paper has been with the authors for three revisions.

APPENDIX

APPENDIX

Three Foundations of TCI Teory Applied to the MNE

Bounded rationality reflects the scarcity of the human mind: “…human behavior is intendedly rational, but only limitedly so” (Simon, 1957: xxiv). Given a complex and uncertain environment, economic actors are unable to know, process and act on all current and future information. Hence they are unable to produce comprehensive contingent claims contracts (Arrow, 1974). Economizing on bounded rationality is widely accepted as critical to both value capture and value creation in the MNE, especially when exploiting the MNE's firm-specific advantages, that is, its proprietary knowledge, which typically exhibits public goods characteristics (Rugman, 1981; Rugman & Verbeke, 2005b). Economizing on bounded rationality is also important when contemplating alternative governance mechanisms for knowledge management; here, the ease of linking the knowledge exploration process with subsequent production and marketing activities, that is, the challenge of effective and efficient innovation in its entirety, is a key consideration.

Bounded reliability reflects the scarcity of making good on open-ended promises: good-faith contractual representations do not always result in the realization of the promised outcomes or performance milestones due to a variety of factors. Safeguards or enforcement mechanisms (Argyres & Liebeskind, 1999) to heighten detection of – and provide punishment for – reneging are symptomatic.

Importantly, the concept of opportunism, which is a key element in Williamsonian TCE, and has been criticized as an inappropriate foundation of management theory (Ghoshal & Moran, 1996), is only one expression of bounded reliability, as assumed implicitly in much of modern TCI theory and visible in numerous modern cases on MNE management. Opportunism implies ex ante false commitments and/or ex post malevolent reneging on commitments. In a Williamsonian world, safeguards need to be established to reduce the probability of opportunistic behavior, and to punish it when it occurs. This is important both when dealing with outside contracting parties in a situation of small numbers bargaining and asset specificity, so as to mitigate the risks of cheating, and to reduce shirking inside the MNE. However, precisely inside the MNE, with managers often committed to spend a substantial portion of their career within a single company (or at least within a single industry), with their professional mobility dependent on their reputation, and with their professional pride to do what is in their mind the best job possible, more common expressions of bounded reliability may prevail, especially benevolent preference reversal over time.

Benevolent preference reversal may result from both recurrent, unintentional over-commitment and recurrent “local” prioritization, with the word “local” referring to the main activities, dispersed in geographic space, for which specific individuals and groups are made responsible. These problems cannot be simply reduced to opportunism issues. Commitments requested by CHQ and intentions expressed to CHQ to achieve a particular outcome/performance level do not always result in the realization of the promised outcome/performance milestones due to a variety of factors, including the misalignment of incentives. In the absence of opportunism, the bounded reliability problem is not that reality turns out differently from prior expectations (which is a mere bounded rationality issue), but that individuals recurrently experience (benevolent) preference reversal over time, a well-known phenomenon in psychology (Steel & König, 2006). For example, at the level of a division, the divisional manager may typically promise the execution of specific investment projects in accordance with CHQ preferences, and commit to specific performance requirements. However, a combination of factors such as a substantial distance in time from any sanction in case of non-achievement, a substantial distance in space from the headquarters’ monitoring apparatus, and the relative proximity and intrinsic satisfaction derived from focusing on autonomous, locally driven investment opportunities with immediate local rewards such as an improvement of relationships with local stakeholders, etc. drives preference reversal. This occurs especially if ultimate performance cannot be appraised objectively and in full (a bounded rationality problem), as is the case when substantial reciprocal interdependencies exist among various subunits in the organization so that an individual's (or unit's) performance cannot be measured accurately.

Apart from describing behavioral reality more correctly and fully than the opportunism concept, there are two additional advantages of adopting the bounded reliability concept: first, opportunism is a concept reflecting abundance (in terms of propensity to cheat and shirk), in contrast to bounded rationality. Bounded reliability, as is the case with bounded rationality, reflects scarcity, in this case scarcity of making good on open-ended promises. Second, for decades there has been a debate between economists and institutional theory scholars on the drivers of change: in economics the main driver is increased efficiency; in institutional theory it is increased legitimacy. A number of empirical articles in business have attempted to “test” these two alternative explanations for changes in managerial settings. By building upon the bounded reliability concept, the need for alternative explanations may in many cases be reduced. For example, historically the relatively slow diffusion of multidivisional governance, in spite of its proven efficiency impacts (not taking into account the causal ambiguity problems associated with such a managerial innovation and the related risk perceptions, nor the possibility of technology-driven rigidities), has been caused in part by the presence of powerful functional groups, in favor of the status quo inside large diversified firms. From an institutional theory perspective, powerful stakeholders considered such a change in governance as illegitimate. From a TCI perspective, governance change would have increased bounded reliability problems, as the stakeholders resisting change would have become “unreliable” (reneging on their employment contract expectations by simply exiting the company or by sabotaging the new system's implementation, etc.), thereby reducing the effectiveness and efficiency of the firm's functioning. However, when a crisis situation unfolded, and a search process was undertaken by the stakeholders concerned to find a solution, the new governance form's legitimacy increased and the danger of reduced reliability of groups previously opposed to the new form faded away. In general terms: expected increases in legitimacy of a particular course of action, such as the choice of a governance form or pattern of behavior, can often reasonably be interpreted as the equivalent of reduced bounded reliability challenges originating from stakeholders able to affect the firm's functioning.

Favorable Organizational Context for Effective and Efficient Knowledge Management in its Entirety

When penetrating foreign markets, firms must first deploy existing, non-location-bound (or internationally transferable) knowledge in those foreign locations (Buckley & Casson, 1976; Rugman, 1981). Second, in order to be successful there, they must also engage in investments, permitting the combination of non-location-bound knowledge from the home country with new, location-bound knowledge in specific host countries or complementary non-location-bound knowledge required to operate profitably abroad. Since both the initial and the recombined knowledge bundles typically have public goods characteristics, the MNE faces a probability of serious loss if these bundles are unintentionally absorbed by external actors, or improperly combined inside the MNE, in host markets. Third, a more recent phenomenon is the need for selectivity (and resulting corporate coherence) in the face of easy access to multiple technologies in multiple foreign locations, meant to create reverse knowledge transfers. Here, the MNE acts as a knowledge network, with several home and host country operations involved as actors in knowledge creation and diffusion activities (Rugman & Verbeke, 2001).

Cantwell's (1995) incisive analysis of MNE technological diversification strategies has demonstrated that three stages of international knowledge recombination must be distinguished. The first stage, covering the post World War I era up to 1970, had MNE foreign subsidiaries engaged primarily in the adaptation of home country knowledge to host country requirements. Technological diversification (albeit largely incremental) thus went hand in hand with geographic diversification. The second stage, which lasted until the mid-1980s, was an era of increased technological interrelatedness, also at the international level. MNE knowledge accumulation from international sources increased, driven partly by a reduction in transport and communication costs, and in many cases by the changing nature of the technological knowledge itself, which permitted its easier diffusion across sectors and national borders. In the third stage, which is still ongoing, new capability creation requires the use of internal networks, with a strong need for selectivity in the choice of interconnected locations (e.g., “higher order” regions), that contribute to new knowledge combinations from various sources: see also Cantwell and Iammarino (2000) and Cantwell and Piscitello (1999). The modern MNE that strategically integrates complementary knowledge sources from different geographic locations (Cantwell, 1989) and harnesses multiple technologies (Cantwell, Dunning, & Janna, 2004a; Cantwell, Gambardella, & Granstrand, 2004b) is thus one that requires, even more than before, a focus on dynamic selectivity in governance. Even in the context of “asset seeking” international diversification (Cantwell et al., 2004a, 2004b), whereby the strong need to manage tacit knowledge and the high potential benefits of learning-by-doing may act as stimuli for internalization, it is important to note that bounded rationality and bounded reliability challenges, though mitigated through internalization as compared with the use of market mechanisms (such as technology licensing), are not eliminated completely (Coase, 1937). Senior managers must monitor and mitigate the effects of bounded rationality and bounded reliability inside the firm, sometimes making extensive use of price-like mechanisms (Hennart, 1991; Rugman & Verbeke, 2003). Importantly, most of the innovation activity described above in large MNEs occurs within global product divisions or regional divisions: see, for example, Rugman (2005).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Verbeke, A., Kenworthy, T. Multidivisional vs metanational governance of the multinational enterprise. J Int Bus Stud 39, 940–956 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400344

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400344

Keywords

Navigation