Introduction

There are different ways of studying health insurance demand, either by considering a static point of view and concentrating on the variable “insured” or “non-insured” or by considering a dynamic process and thus focusing on contract-switching behaviours on the health insurance market. Indeed, the choice of a health insurance contract by a consumer reflects the outcome of the standard trade-off linked to individual preferences and budget constraints. This choice of consumption is modified once a shock occurs: decline in health status, higher prices and so forth. The analysis of switching behaviour allows us to describe the relevant determinants of mobility on the insurance market. Numerous studies have already been carried out to identify the determinants of health insurance demand that are nowadays well attested: age, gender, income, health status, education, warranties, premiums and risk aversion. As the dynamics of demand are studied through switching behaviours, certain analyses have also emphasised market and/or institutional characteristics that may encourage or discourage these behaviours. Laske-Aldershof et al.Footnote 1 provide international comparisons of five countries having a social health insurance system with a choice of health plan. The results point out that switching rates are higher in Germany (5 per cent in 2000) and Switzerland (from 2 per cent in 2000 to 4 per cent in 2002) than in Belgium (<1 per cent before 2000 but reaching 2.5 per cent in 2003), the Netherlands and Israel (<1 per cent in these two countries). The authors explain the higher rates by three main factors: firstly, the type of basic insurance that may offer a possible deduction level (in Switzerland); secondly, the potential monetary gains of switching that depend on the differences between premiums (higher in Germany or Switzerland than in other countries); and, finally, the level of competition. All these factors are obviously linked together and the latter depends on the size of the market, for example, the level of market concentration in Germany and Switzerland is relatively low. Competition also depends on transparency: the health insurance market is always regulated and sometimes a significant part of the warranty package is standardised across private operators (95 per cent in Germany) in order to help policyholders to compare premiums between operators. As emphasised by Laske-Aldershof et al.,Footnote 2 the trade-off between switching costs and expected benefits at least depends on the overall organisation of the health system. The choice of insurer as well as the choice to purchase an additional health insurance contract or not may be free or restricted. For instance, in the context of a group contract with compulsory membership, policyholders did not really decide whether to purchase a supplemental health insurance contract, choose the operator or the warranties of the contract.

Whatever the analyses of individual responses to premium differences in competitive health insurance markets may be, empirical switching rates appear to be much lower than those expected in standard models of consumer demand in the case of competitive markets. Thus, studies have been carried out in order to stress and discuss the nature of barriers preventing the expression of individual preferences in the trade-off and/or in the selection actually made. Different explanations have been explored to understand this phenomenon. First, there are limitations on consumers' rationalityFootnote 3 and on their ability to opt for efficient contracts in highly competitive health insurance markets. Moreover, Frank and LamiraudFootnote 4 have shown that a broader range of contracts, meaning more competition, might be inefficient as the information available for the consumer becomes unreadable, thus decreasing consumers' responsiveness to differences in premiums. This has to be considered in addition to well-known transparency problems in the context of health insurance.Footnote 5 Second, there are different types of switching costs (suspension period, additional premium for late enrolment, etc.)Footnote 6 and the monetary benefits may appear quite low compared to the total cost. Another barrier to switching from one insurer to another is the provision of an insurance package including health insurance and provident benefits. This type of contract is currently offered by operators in the context of group contracts, making it difficult for consumers to really compare different premiums as it is much more complex to identify the price of each type of warranty.

In France, health insurance demand has recently been analysed from the static point of view. Saliba and VentelouFootnote 7 studied individual determinants for subscribing or not subscribing to a supplementary health insurance contract. As for the dynamic process, switching behaviours have also been studied through the influence of socio-economic and health characteristics. Working on a representative sample of the French population, Grignon and SittaFootnote 8 have estimated the annual switching rate in the competitive health insurance market at 12 per cent (mobility between different private health insurance operators). The authors considered a rather large number of factors to explain the switching behaviour and assumed that the choice to switch may be either the result of an individual trade-off on the one hand, or that it may be constrained on the other. Thus they showed that the switching behaviour appears to be motivated as much by individual characteristics such as age, education, state of health, etc., as by circumstances. The authors particularly emphasised the significant role of “a change in individual social economic status.”Footnote 9 These results suggest that switching behaviour could be individually concentrated at a period of life such as retirement. This period is currently characterised by a potential income effect due to a decrease or increase in financial resources. Moreover, depending on the way in which individuals obtained their private health insurance contract, that is, by individual decision (individual contract) or collectively at work (group contract), retirement can be associated with an additional price effect due to the potential increase in premiums. This increase may be the result of the loss both of the employer's subsidy in the payment of the premium and of the benefit of pooling risk pricing. The impact of potential premium increases has been quite extensively studied in the U.S. Among others, Rogowski and KarolyFootnote 10 showed that access to post-retirement health insurance has a rather important effect on retirement: “Among older male workers, those with retiree health benefit offers are 68 per cent more likely to retire (and those with non-employment-based insurance are 44 per cent more likely to retire) than their counterpart who would lose employment-based health insurance upon retirement.”Footnote 11 However, the debate in the U.S. concentrates much more on the role of health insurance in mobility on the labour market and more particularly in retirement decisions, whereas in France the debate focuses on the impact of retirement on mobility in the private health insurance market.

In the French context, no study has yet been carried out on the influence of differences in prices on switching behaviour at the time of retirement. This is probably due to the high complexity of supplementary health insurance added to difficulties in collecting the actual prices paid by individuals,Footnote 12 making it difficult to simultaneously control variations in premiums and warranties. Transition to retirement constitutes a specific moment for studying health insurance demand. Indeed, the transition to retirement most often occurs along with an exogenous shock in income (upwards or downwards) and with potential increases in private health insurance premiums due to the funding and charging mechanisms of group contract premiums. Thus a high switching rate during the transition to retirement for all policyholders can be expected (income effect), with a much higher rate among the enrollees of group contracts (specific price effect). The purpose of this paper is to investigate if this is indeed the case, controlling elsewhere for a number of other variables.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows. The next section describes the French context of private health insurance supplementing public health insurance. By giving details on the legislation and on the tax benefits associated with each type of contract (compulsory group contract, voluntary group contract and individual contract), we explain how the former nature of contract may be considered as a proxy for the price increase. The subsequent section provides a description of the data set and the model used. Our results and estimations are presented in the penultimate section that is followed by a discussion in the final section.

The former nature of a contract: a proxy of the potential price increase

In France, health insurance is divided into two parts: public insurance and supplementary private health insurance. Public health insurance is compulsory and universalFootnote 13 and funds about 77 per cent of health care expenditure, a share that has been quite stable over the past 10 years. Its contribution is particularly high for hospital care (92 per cent), lower for ambulatory care (66 per cent) and poor for some specific types of care such as eyewear and dental prostheses.Footnote 14 Supplementary private health insurance covers the payment of the share not covered by public health insurance. The share of total expenditure funded by private supplementary insurance might appear rather modest (around 13 per cent of total health care expenditure) even if supplemental private health insurance is now recognised as playing a fundamental role in access to health care. The share of health care expenditure that may be automatically funded by private health insurance is high when the share of co-payments not covered by public insurance is highest (dental care, eyewear, and extra-fees for consultations with certain specialists). This is the reason why nearly 90 per cent of French people benefit from a private supplementary insurance scheme (despite marked heterogeneity across private contracts in terms of the warranties provided) and why public authorities implemented a voucher system to favour access to private insurance for the poorFootnote 15 since 2004.

The market for private insurance in which individuals and employers purchase contracts is highly competitive. The French private health insurance market is weakly concentrated. The top 10 operators account for hardly 25 per cent of total turnover, whereas in the German social health insurance market, for example, this share exceeds 50 per cent.Footnote 16 Three types of insurers are active in the French market: (1) mutuelles (mutual benefit societies), these are the historical providers of such insurance and are non-profit organisations mainly offering individual contracts (75 per cent of their turnover) with still limited use of risk-rating or risk-selection strategies; (2) provident institutions (PI), which are non-profit organisations mostly specialised in compulsory group contracts (80 per cent of their turnover); (3) finally, there are the commercial health insurance companies which are for-profit organisations that share their health insurance activities between individual and group markets (60 per cent of their turnover comes from individual contracts and 40 per cent from group contracts) and practice relatively strong adjustments for individual risk in individual contracts. The three types of operators differ in many respects: their organisational objectives, the share health represents in their respective overall portfolios, the way they are regulated, etc.Footnote 17 Supplementary health insurance contracts can be purchased either by individuals themselves or by their employers, the latter adding them as a benefit to the employee's salary package (in 2003, 40 per cent of French firms employing 72 per cent of employees offered group contracts according to a Protection Sociale Complementaire d'Entreprise survey). Nearly two policyholders in three obtain their coverage through their employer. Usually and whatever the type of insurer, group contracts offer several advantages compared to individual contracts. On average, the warranties offered are much more generous than those available through individual contracts.Footnote 18 This can be explained by a lower degree or even a lack, in the case of compulsory contracts, of adverse selection in these contracts. Moreover, for a given set of warranties, premiums are lower than those achievable in the context of individual contracts. This is due simultaneously to the employer's contribution, which finances on average half of the premium,Footnote 19 lower loading fees due to economies of scale associated with purchasing insurance through a groupFootnote 20 and finally, to tax exemptions for employees' contributions to the residual premium for compulsory contracts. Moreover, community-rated premiums (systematically for compulsory contracts and almost systematically for optional contracts) offer an additional price benefit to employees, though mainly for older ones.

Considering the financial advantages offered to workers enrolled in a health insurance group contract, it seems coherent to assume that the switching of private supplementary coverage may differ from one type of policyholder to another. Thus, the switching behaviour of new retirees should be explained by the nature of the former contract. In the French context, the difference of magnitude of premiums increases at retirement between group and individual contracts, offering the opportunity to study the marginal price effect on switching behaviours. Indeed, the nature of contract (compulsory group contract, voluntary group contract and individual contract) may be considered as an indirect measurement of the price effect. In this analysis, we therefore focus on the role of the nature of the former contract (prior to retirement) and check for a large number of individual characteristics that may influence health insurance demand. Moreover, we pay particular attention to the effect of the type of private insurer managing the contract owned prior to retirement.

At retirement, former group contract beneficiaries lose all the financial advantages mentioned above. The Evin Law of 31 December 1989, which was the first major public intervention in the private health insurance market, aimed primarily at limiting “risk selection” and increasing the portability of warranties. For compulsory group contracts, the law requires insurers to offer the new retiree a contract providing similar warranties to the group contract as well as cap the increase in premiums. In fact, by adding different premium increases due to the loss of group pricing (capped at 50 per cent), and to the loss of the employer's contribution, the premium actually paid by the new retiree can increase by almost 200 per cent. Sharper increases may be observed in the context of voluntary group contracts for which increases in premiums are not regulated by law.

Data and methods

Data source and sample construction

This study is based on the Health, Health Care and Insurance Survey (ESPS) carried out between 1994 and 2004 on French individuals covered by the public health insurance system.Footnote 21 For each policyholder, in addition to data on the insurance contract, the panelFootnote 22 includes standard socio-economic characteristics and individual indicators of health status. This survey, performed on around 20,000 individuals, was carried out every year between 1994 and 1997 and became bi-annual afterwards. Between 1994 and 2004, we identified three observation dates per policyholder (T1, T2, T3): the individuals interviewed in 1994 and in 1995 were gathered together to constitute the first observation date (T1). They were re-interviewed in 1998 (constituting T2) and finally in 2002 (constituting T3). The individuals interviewed in 1996 and in 1997 were gathered together to constitute the first observation date of these individuals (T1). They were re-interviewed in 2000 (T2) and finally in 2004 (T3) (see Figure 1). In order to pick up new retirees we had to select individuals whose status had changed from “in-work” to “retired” between two observation dates. This enabled us to compare their complementary health coverage provider just before and just after retirement (with a 4-year interval or, less frequently, an 8-year interval). Only subscribers of a private supplementary health insurance contract have been retained as we assumed that switching from one private operator to another is the result of their own decision. This excludes de facto the beneficiaries of Couverture Maladie Universelle ComplémentaireFootnote 23 (CMU-C) mainly administrated by local public funds. Furthermore, because of recoding problems, we excluded individuals who subscribed to several insurance contracts.

Figure 1
figure 1

Three observation dates per policyholder between 1994 and 2004.

Finally, the sample provides information on 910 subscribers whose average retirement age is 59 (see Table 1). The database provides a wide variety of information for each subscriber, which can be classified in two groups. On the one hand, the database provides standard individual characteristics such as age, sex, education and date dependant variables such as occupation,Footnote 24 incomeFootnote 25 and health status. Health is measured by several indicators: the vital risk corresponding to a higher probability of death established on the basis of individuals' response to a statement on a six-point Likert scale, that is, from “no essential risk” to “a definite poor prognosis” and defined as an 80 per cent probability of death within 5 years; disability based on potential chronic illnesses resulting in a permanent handicap determined by an answer on an eight-point Likert scale, that is, from “no impairment” to “permanently bed-ridden”; and, last but not least, perceived health status based on an individual score from “very poor health” (0) to “excellent health” (10). On the other hand, the database gives information on private insurance contracts such as the nature of contract before and after retirement (compulsory, voluntary group or individual contractFootnote 26), the type of private operator (mutual benefit society, provident institution or insurance company) and the individual assessment of the warranties provided by the insurer particularly for specialist care: “poor opinion” of payments, “fair opinion” or “good opinion.”

Table 1 Description of the 910 retirees

We analyse the role of all these factors in the decision to switch from one insurer to another.

The data allows us to observe the switching decision as long as the individual opts for a different provider; however, we do not identify the change of contract within the same provider. For the sake of simplicity, we talk about the switching (or not) of supplementary health provider at the moment of retirement, knowing that we underestimate the overall switching rate.

Exploratory analysis

In the database, almost 22 per cent of individuals benefit from a compulsory group contract, 25 per cent from a voluntary group contract and 49 per cent from an individual contract. Table 2 provides summary statistics about switching rates according to the nature of the former contract: 51 per cent of individuals affiliated with a compulsory group contract switch at retirement, while the figures are 39 per cent and 23 per cent, respectively for beneficiaries of a voluntary group contract and those of individual contracts. These switching rates suggest that the assumption of a significant impact of the nature of the former contract is relevant. Nevertheless, all the other variables and particularly certain other characteristics of contracts may influence the switching decision. For instance, the fact that the three types of providers supply different forms of contracts whether they target individual or collective demand may bias immediate interpretations of descriptive statistics. Mutual benefit societies and commercial insurance companies mainly intervene on individual contract supply (respectively 75 per cent and 60 per cent of their turnover), whereas provident institutions (PI) concentrate on group contracts (80 per cent of their turnover). Table 3 provides a more detailed description of switching behaviours regarding the type of former provider. Switching behaviours are more frequent among those formerly insured by an insurance company (55 per cent) vs. those formerly covered by a provident institution (43 per cent) and finally vs. individuals formerly covered by a mutual benefit society (25 per cent). Table 4 shows the type of provider selected among policyholders who decided to switch regarding their respective former types of provider. Indeed, each of them may decide whether to change their type of provider or remain affiliated with a provider of the same type. Among policyholders who decided to switch, only 41 per cent of those formerly insured by an insurance company, that is, those who switch most, selected another insurance company while a third of them opted for a mutual benefit society. Among the 43 per cent of those formerly covered by a PI who decided to switch, only 38 per cent of them decided to select another PI. The policyholders who switch least are those formerly affiliated to a mutual benefit society (only a quarter of them) and 76 per cent of them select another mutual benefit society.

Table 2 Switching rate according to nature of contract
Table 3 Switching rate relating to type of provider
Table 4 Type of provider chosen by policyholders who decided to switch

In order to analyse efficiently the price effect whose proxy is the nature of the contract, we had to isolate the relative effect of all these variables by running a model considering that “all other factors are equal.”

Method

A probit model was used to estimate the probability of switching providers. Taking into account that the nature of a former contract could generate quite large ranges of increase in premiums at retirement, we had to estimate switching behaviour by controlling effects that are not directly linked to the nature of contract. Thus, we considered the binary variable Yi defined by Yi=1 if the individual switched and Yi=0 otherwise.

where Zi represents the nature of the former contract (compulsory, voluntary or individual); Xi and ΔRi represent control variables: Xi is a vector of individual characteristics before retirement (education, age of retirement, retirement wave, type of provider, individual assessment of payments for specialist care, public fund, public co-payment exemption and vital risk) and ΔRi represents the difference in income before and after retirement: “same income,” “higher income after” and “lower income after.” Standard error ɛ is assumed to follow a cumulative normal distribution.

This model allows for calculating marginal effects. We estimated the individual probability to switch through the estimation of parameters (α, β, γ and δ), then computed these estimated probabilities to calculate the mean probabilities for the different groups defined by our variables, every thing else being equal. The magnitudes of the differences in mean probabilities were analysed in order to understand the differences in switching behaviour.

Results

Table 5 presents the results of the probit regression. All factors being equal, the switching probability is significantly higher for individuals enrolled in a group contract before retirement than for those who hold an individual contract, that is, it is 13 per cent higher for retirees formerly covered by a voluntary group contract and 21 per cent higher for those previously covered by a compulsory contract. The higher switching rate observed for group contract holders can be explained by the various financial benefits available for employees enrolled in a group contract. Indeed, retirement may lead to potentially higher increases in premiums due to the loss of pooled pricing on the one hand and to the loss of the employer's subsidy on the other, both generating a sharp rise in premiums. The difference in estimated switching behaviour between policyholders formerly enrolled in a group contract and those formerly insured by an individual contract is in line with our price effect assumption: it emphasises the expected rational behaviour of the individuals facing a high increase in prices.

Table 5 Marginal probability of switching behaviour

Among policyholders formerly enrolled in a group contract, the probability to switch is higher for those whose membership was compulsory than for those for whom subscription was voluntary (+21pts vs. +13pts). Due to the reality of the group contracts market, this result does not have to be explained in terms of differences in premiums variation. Indeed, although it is not obligatory for employers to finance a share of the premium in the case of voluntary group contracts, they do so in practice and it appears that average levels of participation are similar for all group contracts (respectively 49 per cent for voluntary membership and 52 per cent for compulsory membership).Footnote 27 Moreover, whereas providers have to apply group pricing in the case of voluntary group contracts, it appears that almost all of them apply this pricing model (only 4 per cent adjust the price to individual risk).Footnote 28 Thus, the lower estimated probability to switch in the case of voluntary group contracts can be explained in another way: the decision to subscribe or not is in itself a rational choice of the optimal coverage already based on cost and personal needs (utility), whereas in the case of a compulsory group contract, everything is already established and there is no room for choice. Therefore, even though the average level of warranties in the case of compulsory contracts is relatively high, the warranties included in the package are not necessarily tailored to the needs of retirees.Footnote 29

Everything else being equal, policyholders covered by a commercial insurance company before retirement changed their insurer more frequently than those previously covered by a mutual benefit society (+26pts). It should be recalled that among policyholders who decided to switch their provider at retirement, more than half formerly insured through a commercial insurance company also change their type of provider (mutual benefit society or PI). This higher probability is the result of two different switching behaviours: first, changes related to an anticipation of an increase in premiums (over time) due to a significant pricing risk often used by the insurance company may explain the choice of a mutual benefit society or a PI. Second, greater competition among insurance companies offering broader ranges of warrantiesFootnote 30 may also explain a higher switching rate within this type of operator.

It appears that the vital risk prior to retirement is the sole indicator of health status that has a significant impact on switching behaviour: subscribers in very poor health (high vital risk) have a lower probability (−10 per cent) to switch from one provider to another one compared to rather healthy individuals (no vital risk). This result could suggest that individuals in poor health face certain barriers to switching, perhaps because of selection implemented by providers. However, although these results are interesting, they are not very robust. In fact, our model does not highlight significant effects of health status with the other indicators tested, namely “disability” and “perceived health status.” Likewise, we tested the assumption that change in health status (being in better or in worse health after retirement) impacts switching behaviour. Unlike the results obtained by Grignon and Sitta,Footnote 31 our model failed to highlight a significant role of change in health status on the retirees' switching behaviour.

Moreover, note that individuals who do not have public co-payments, mainly due to long-term disease (ALD), do not adopt a specific switching behaviour, despite the fact that this classification (ALD) reflects rather deteriorated health. This result could suggest that public insurance coverage can significantly reduce the additional risk characterising these individuals, placing them in a comparable situation in the private insurance market to other retirees, despite the “poor” health observed.

Individuals insured before retirement by the one of the two other public funds, RSI (Régime social des indépendants) or MSA (Mutualité sociale agricole), have a much lower probability (−13pts) to switch than individuals affiliated with the main public funds (Caisse Nationale d'Assurance Maladie des Travailleurs Salari, CNAMTS). In our sample, most of the individuals not covered by CNAMTS are beneficiaries of the RSI. Until 2002, the majority of those insured by RSI had to bear lower public compensations than any other policyholders. Consequently, their lower switching behaviour suggests that they are used to relying more on their private insurance to gain access to the health care system than policyholders covered by the main public funds (CNAMTS).

We also noted that, all other factors being equal, retirees who had experienced a reduction in their resources do not change provider more frequently. This result suggests that income may not play a significant role. This unexpected result is probably the consequence of the approximate and irregular method for monitoring income through time, leading to the creation of increasingly broad income bands. This problem of collecting income data is compounded by that of no available data.

We observed that the most highly educated policyholders have a lower probability of changing provider. This result, which contradicts the intuition that the most educated individuals have easier access to information, is however in line with previous results obtained in general population studies (Grignon and Sitta, 2003).Footnote 32 One can assume that the level of education (high school and lower/higher education) reached 40 years ago is not a good proxy for the ability of a new retiree to read and understand a contract for health insurance. Indeed, experience gained over time reduces the effect of initial education.

Discussion

The results of our study show that switching behaviours from one private health insurer to another are relatively frequent during the transition to retirement, since an average of one retiree in three decides to switch. Compared with the estimated switching rates on samples of the general population, it appears that change in status in the labour market is a major cause of mobility in the market for private health insurance. Far from contradicting earlier works, our results confirm the findings of Grignon and Sitta.Footnote 33 Retirement is a key period when the effects of both income and prices through insurance premiums accumulate.

Our results confirm that there is a price effect as policyholders formerly enrolled in a group contract switch much more frequently than those formerly benefiting from an individual contract. We also show that switching behaviours cannot be explained only in terms of the addition of different price effects: for comparable levels of premium increases, policyholders enrolled in compulsory group contracts change more frequently than those enrolled in voluntary group contracts, probably to take advantage of the transition to retirement to build up a set of insurance warranties that suits them better.

However, our study is limited in some respects. The main limitation is a consequence of our data: we underestimate mobility on the private health insurance market as we only consider inter-company mobility. Indeed, we have no data on intra-company mobility, meaning that we only know when a policyholder switches from one private insurer to another, but not when this policyholder changes from one contract to another with the same private insurer. Another limitation concerns our method. Indeed, the model used allows us to isolate the effect of the nature of contract (that we consider as being a proxy of the price effect) from the other factors introduced in the model. The price effect could be biased if the nature of the initial contract is linked to unobservable variables that may influence the decision to change provider. More precisely, our model is based on the assumption that all policyholders have the same degree of risk aversion. If we decided not to keep this hypothesis, then people with higher risk aversion and who are assumed to be the least mobile on the supplementary private health insurance market, could not initially be distributed randomly between the different contracts (group or individual). We could, for example, consider that policyholders who previously benefited from a compulsory group contract are more likely to be averse to risk. This distortion exists and is not controlled by the model. However, this distortion illustrating that the choice to work for a specific organisation could depend on whether or not it offers a group insurance contract is not very significant in the French context (it is less significant than in the American market, for instance). Indeed in France, private insurance coverage supplements a rather large but non-uniform share of public insurance coverage. Moreover, another explanation for this distortion may be the fact that independent workers, usually assumed to be less averse to risk than people on a payroll, are under-represented among group contract beneficiaries. This does not distort our results as we control the characteristic of being an independent worker indirectly via their public health insurance, namely RSI.

Our results clearly show that mobility is high during this particular period of retirement characterised by a change in both socioeconomic status and in risk status due to age. However, private health insurance in France only covers a segment of the policyholder's health care, that is, primary care, eye and dental care, whereas hospital care is almost entirely covered by public health insurance. The question is whether the respective shares of private and public health insurance are likely to increase mobility during the transition to retirement. Due to the lower overall risk covered by private insurance, individuals might be expected to be more sensitive to price changes corresponding to a more elastic insurance demand, which should be reflected in higher switching rates. On the contrary, if we consider private health insurance as a superior good, and since public health insurance covers the most expensive part of the risk, then those individuals who feel “richer” should raise their share of private health insurance expenditure. It could be interesting to focus on this question due to the changes affecting the respective shares of private and public health insurance.

Moreover, in order to understand more precisely the determinants of the health insurance demand of new retirees, it could be very useful to obtain information on the content of the different contracts in order to run a qualitative analysis of insurance demand. The heterogeneity of supplementary health insurance contracts (in terms of the warranties included) should increase due to the gradual expansion of the scope of private insurance. Thus, purchasing a supplementary insurance contract does not guarantee full access to health care and such analysis could become increasingly relevant.

New retirees are one of the most mobile population groups in the supplementary health insurance market. Considering the high level of saturation of this market, this group can be an attractive target for insurers. The downside is that new retirees are likely to be in a fragile position due to more difficult access to private health insurance and therefore to the health care system in general.