Introduction

Assumptions about future mortality rates are an integral part of the pricing, reserving, and risk management of insurance companies or pension funds offering annuity and life insurance contracts. Systematic deviations of actual mortality rates from these assumptions can pose a serious threat to the financial stability of those businesses and to the economic well-being of policy-holders. Thus, there has been considerable recent research into developing models that allow for stochastic mortality, that is, models that allow for systematic deviations from mortality trends.

In another stream of demographic research, several epidemiological studies find that mortality rates react to changes in macroeconomic conditions. By combining results from both fields of study, a recent contribution shows that the mortality index k t in the well-known Lee–Carter model is significantly correlated with macroeconomic changes.Footnote 1 This insight is the inspiration for the present study, which develops a dynamic asset-liability model for the assessment of the overall impact of macroeconomic fluctuations on the financial stability of a life insurance company. In this model, both assets and liabilities are allowed to react to the state of the economy. Exemplary simulation results for realistically chosen model parameters show that insolvency probabilities are considerably higher when the reaction of mortality rates to changes in the economic indicators is incorporated compared to scenarios where this relationship is ignored. This finding is robust to variations in the age of the insureds, the insurance portfolio size, the equity base and the share of assets invested in stocks.

The paper is organised as follows. Section “Related literature” contains a review of relevant literature. This is followed, in Section “The simulation framework”, by setting up the simulation model for the insurance company. Results of different simulation scenarios are presented in Section “Simulation results”. A summary and conclusions are provided in Section “Conclusion and outlook”.

Related literature

The field of mortality modelling has undergone substantial development in the past few years.Footnote 2 The earliest and still the most popular model was proposed by Lee and Carter.Footnote 3 This model is widely employed both in the academic literature and by practitioners working for pension funds, life insurance companies and public pension systems. The original approach has seen several extensions,Footnote 4 and has been applied to mortality data of many countries, including the G-7 countries, Australia, Belgium, China and South Korea, and Spain.Footnote 5 For mortality modelling, the Lee–Miller variant is generally viewed as the standard.Footnote 6 It performs well in a ten-population comparison study of five variants or in extensions of the Lee–Carter method.Footnote 7

The key driver of mortality dynamics in the Lee–Carter model is the index of the level of mortality k t .Footnote 8 This variable is typically characterised as the dominant temporal pattern in the decline of mortality, a random period effect, or simply as a latent variable.Footnote 9 However, a recent study using data for six OECD countries (Australia, Canada, Japan, the Netherlands, the United Kingdom and the United States) reveals that the mortality index in the Lee–Carter model is not merely an unobserved, latent variable that fluctuates erratically.1 The study reports significant correlations between changes in k t and real gross domestic product (GDP) growth rates or unemployment rate changes for all six countries studied over the period 1950–2006. The results of cointegration analyses provided in the study confirm that these correlations result from a long run causal relationship between mortality and macroeconomic fluctuations. However, further analysis of the mortality rates from six main causes of death shows that most cause-specific mortality rates show pronounced trends over the past decades. These trends change the composition of deaths and alter how total mortality reacts to external factors such as macroeconomic fluctuations. A comparison of the two subperiods 1950–1979 and 1980–2006 then shows that the link between the economy and total mortality is subject to a major change that even results in a reversal from procyclical to countercyclical in the latter subperiod.

Hanewald's findings for the period 1950–2006 are in line with results of several previous studies that relate (age-specific) mortality rates directly to macroeconomic conditions. Ruhm was the first to discover that total mortality, as well as several cause-specific mortality rates (e.g., motor vehicle fatalities, deaths from cardiovascular disease, liver ailments or flu/pneumonia), fluctuated procyclically in the United States over the period 1972–1991.Footnote 10 Similar procyclical patterns were observed for mortality rates in France, Germany, Japan, Spain, Sweden and for 23 OECD countries over the period 1960–1997.Footnote 11

There is evidence for the structural change in the link between mortality and the economy, as well. For Japan, a structural break in the effect of macroeconomic fluctuations on total mortality occured at ages 20–44 and 45–64 years in 1978.Footnote 12 An explanation is found in changes in the composition of causes of death which alter the reaction of aggregate mortality to economic conditions. In most industrialised countries, an increase is observed in both deaths attributable to (countercyclical) diabetes and hypertensive disease12 and in (acyclical/countercyclical) cancer deaths.Footnote 13 Apart from that there was a dramatic decline in (procyclical) cardiovascular diseases mortality at the beginning of the 1970s.Footnote 14 Furthermore, reductions in (procyclical) motor vehicle fatalities are reported for a large number of OECD countries.Footnote 15

The financial impact of systematic mortality risk on a life insurer or pension fund is analysed in several models. A large number of studies tries to quantify the impact of stochastic mortality on insurers’ risk exposure, many of them focusing on systematic mortality improvements (“longevity risk”).Footnote 16 Other studies analyse strategies to manage systematic mortality risk such as natural hedging opportunities between annuity and life insurance business, optimal asset allocation strategies or the design of new insurance products.Footnote 17 None of the studies, however, accounts for the systematic dependency of mortality rates on the economic environment as proxied by real GDP, which is the contribution of this paper.

The simulation framework

The model for the insurance business

Our aim is to assess the overall impact of macroeconomic fluctuations on a life insurer's solvency. We set up a dynamic asset liability model of a life insurance company as described below.

Consider a newly founded life insurance company. At the beginning of its first year, in t=0, it writes I0 homogeneous term-life contractsFootnote 18 with annually constant premium P per contract. All insureds are assumed to be of age x. The contract duration is for T years and the death benefit is B. For each contract, the premium P is collected immediately. Shareholders contribute a fixed proportion γ of the premium income I0·P as equity capital E0. The sum of premiums and equity comprises the insurer's assets A0.

We assess the insurer's financial stability by its insolvency probability. Insolvency occurs when the firm's equity—measured at market value—is negative at the end of the year. Insolvent insurance firms are not allowed to continue operating. The target variable of our analysis is the multi-period insolvency probability ψ t of the insurance firm, which is defined by the probability that, at the end of year t, one of the following conditions is true: for an insurer being solvent at year t−1 the insurer's equity capital is negative in year t, or the insurer was already insolvent in the previous year. This measure provides a potential insurance buyer (or regulator) with an important metric to evaluate a contract's financial quality: For various planning horizons t, it directly gives the probability that the insurer will still exist at that future period and will be able to pay out insurance benefits in case the policy-holder were to die.

Equity capital at time t is the difference between the market value of assets A t and the liabilities L t at the end of the year:

Asset values are given by:

where R t is the stochastic investment return (i.e., exp(rate of return)), B·(−ΔI t ) are the claims payments, Δ is the lag operator and D t is the annual dividend paid out to shareholders.

With PV t [·] denoting a present value operator, which is specified in Section “Random variables and stochastic processes”, the market value of year-end liabilities L t is given by:

Dividends D t at the end of the year are a constant fraction d of the insurer's net income for that year N t when N t is positive; zero otherwise. Formally, D t is given by:

where net income N t is defined as:

Random variables and stochastic processes

We now define the stochastic processes driving our model. Real GDP is introduced first; it is the fundamental link between the other random variables, that is, the number of surviving insureds I t (driven by the mortality index k t ) and capital market returns R t .

Following previous work, a lognormal distribution is assumed for real GDP.Footnote 19 Thus annual changes in log real GDP are given by:

where μ GDP and σ GDP denote the mean and standard deviation of real GDP growth rates and ɛ GDP,t is a standardised normal random variable.

The number of deaths at the end of each year—ΔI t follows a binomial distribution B(It−1, qx+t−1,t). We hereby account for unsystematic mortality risk, that is, the fact that the actual number of deaths might deviate from the expected number. The probability for each insured aged x+t−1 at the beginning of a year to die at the end of the year t is denoted as qx+t−1, t. Considering stochastic mortality, that is, accounting for systematic mortality risk, the probability qx+t−1,t itself is also a random variable realising in t. Age-specific mortality probabilities qx,t are derived from the central death rates mx,t of a Lee–Carter-type model, using the approximation:Footnote 20

According to the Lee–Carter approach, and abstracting from age-specific shocks,Footnote 21 central death rates mx,t are given by:

where a x is an age-specific constant and b x describes the sensitivity of age-specific mortality rates to changes in the mortality index k t , which is a random variable.

As in the original Lee and Carter model, the stochastic process for the mortality index k t is modelled as a random walk with drift:

with ɛk,t being a standardised normal random variable.

In summary, there are two sources of randomness in our model for the number of deaths. One is based in the uncertainty regarding the path of the underlying mortality index k t . The other source of randomness results from sampling the insurance portfolio.

Distribution of the asset return R t depends on the insurer's asset allocation decisions. Following Kling et al.,Footnote 22 we allow for two lognormally distributed investment opportunities: stocks and bonds. Let rs,t denote the stock log-return in period t and rb,t the bond log-return, and let α∈[0, 1] be the fraction of assets invested in stocks. Then, the return of the annually rebalanced asset portfolio R t is given by:

where:

with μ s , μ b , σ s and σ b denoting the mean and standard deviation of log-returns, and ɛs,t and ɛb,t being standardised normal random variables.

In a last step, we specify the value of the insurer's liabilities at the end of each year L t , which were introduced in Eq. (3). At the end of every year, the insurer observes the realised bond returns and the current level of the mortality index k t . The insurer uses the latter as a starting point for projecting future mortality rates; observed bond returns are used to discount expected liabilities. Thus, the market value of liabilities—in the instant between that year's claim payments and next year's premium income—is given by:

where i qx,t is the probability that an insured aged x will die after age x+i−1, while i px,t is the probability that an insured aged x will survive at least another i years. The insurer calculates both probabilities conditional on the information available at time t. In Eq. (12), the present value calculus is specified by taking the expectation of future cash flows with respect to the real-world probability measure without further risk adjustments. Thus, we assume that the insurer is unaware of any correlations between mortality and GDP or the capital market development, that is, the insurer does not consider the systematic nature of mortality risk.

In summary, economic and demographic randomness in our model are induced by the following random variables: the mortality index k t , real GDP growth rates and bond and stock returns. The main contribution of this paper is to account for the interaction of these factors, especially the dependency between mortality rates and economic conditions, which we accomplish by allowing for a correlation matrix with nonzero off-diagonal elements for the random variables ɛ k,t , ɛ s,t , ɛ b,t and ɛ GDP,t .Footnote 23

Numerical calibration of the model

Calibration of the model involves estimating parameters of the stochastic processes from empirical data, as well as setting insurance contract and management parameters. We begin with a base scenario, but will vary several of the parameters later on in the analysis.

Management assumptions

The fixed proportion γ of the first premium income I0·P raised as initial equity capital E0 is set to 0.1. The dividend ratio d, that is, the constant fraction of the insurer's net income paid out to shareholders, is set to 0.1. The asset fraction α that is invested in stocks is set to 0.3. This parameter set results in reasonably small one-period insolvency probabilities.

Contract characteristics

We consider a term-life insurance contract with a duration of T=10 years and a death benefit of B=$100,000. This contract is sold to I0=10,000 insureds in t=0. In the base scenario, all insureds are male and of age x=40. Mortality data is available up until 2005; therefore, the simulation starts with t=0 at the beginning of 2006.

The fair premium for an individual contract is calculated by solving Eq. (13) for P fair :

Thus, the same assumptions used to calculate future liabilities in Eq. (12) apply for premium calculation. The contract is sold at a premium P that includes a proportional loading λ on the fair premium, which, in the base scenario, is set to 0.1:

Stochastic processes

Death rates and population size for the United States were obtained from the Human Mortality Database.Footnote 24 A series for real GDP was obtained from the website of the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis.Footnote 25 For calibration of the return processes we use annual total returns of large company stocks and U.S. treasury bills.Footnote 26 In the following, these series are referred to as real GDP, stock returns and bond returns.

The Lee–Carter model was estimated with the R package demography.Footnote 27 The Lee–Miller variant was chosenFootnote 28; it has been widely adopted as the standard Lee–Carter method6 and involves estimating the model for the latter half of the twentieth century.Footnote 29 Male and female forecasts are treated as two separate applications of the basic Lee–Carter approach.Footnote 30 The model is estimated with the same upper age limit as in the original (85 years) article by Lee and Carter and a minimum age of 30 years. Figure 1 plots the estimated parameters a x and b x that are needed to derive age-specific death rates m x,t from the mortality index k t. Figure 2 plots the mortality index k t that was extracted for U.S. males for 1950–2005, together with the 2006–2015 forecast.

Figure 1
figure 1

Fitted values for a x (dashed, right axis) and b x (solid, left axis) for ages 30–85.

Figure 2
figure 2

Mortality index k t , fitted values 1950–2005, forecast 2006–2015 with 95 per cent confidence band.

The extracted time series for the mortality index k t , together with the time series for GDP and returns, are used to estimate the parameters and correlation structure of the four exogenous stochastic processes. Based on results from Hanewald that document a structural change in the correlation structure between real GDP growth rates and the mortality index in six OECD countries over the period 1950–2005, we decide to use a shorter period for estimating the parameters. Using a bivariate regression where changes in the estimated mortality index k t are regressed on the real GDP growth rates we identify a significant break point for 1989 with the Chow breakpoint testFootnote 31 and therefore use the period 1989–2005 for parameter estimation.

Table 1 summarises the estimated parameters and correlation structure.

Table 1 Estimation results, 1989–2005

Simulation results

Assuming the exemplary set of model parameters described above, the insurance company model was simulated with 100,000 iterations using the Latin Hypercube technique.Footnote 32 As a benchmark for comparison, we first simulate a version of the model that ignores the impact of macroeconomic changes on mortality rates. This scenario assumes that the mortality index k t in the Lee–Carter model is uncorrelated with economic conditions as reflected by the processes for GDP, stocks and bonds, that is, entries in the last column of the correlation matrix in Table 1 are set to zero (except the last value, which is one). Next, the scenario employing the full correlation structure is simulated. The difference in insolvency probabilities between the two scenarios is a measure of model misspecification risk. Results are given in Figure 3.

Figure 3
figure 3

Multi-period insolvency probability ψ t , base parameter calibration, full correlation structure vs. reduced correlation structure.

Multi-period insolvency probabilities increase over time in both scenarios. There are two reasons for this: first, confidence intervals for the realisations of the random variables, for example, for the mortality index k t (c.p., Figure 2), broaden with an increasing time horizon; and second, insolvency probabilities cumulate because firms that become insolvent remain insolvent.

Looking at Figure 3 reveals that employing the full correlation structure increases the insolvency probability for every time horizon considered. Thus, ignoring the correlations between the mortality index k t and the economic variables will result in a systematic underestimation of the true insolvency probability. This will occur because the true correlation structure links assets and liabilities in a very unfavourable way: a drop in GDP, in tendency, coincides with lower stock and bond returns, that is, with a shrinking asset base, along with a higher mortality index k t , resulting in higher liabilities. Both effects take a toll on equity capital. In absolute numbers, the difference in insolvency probabilities between the two scenarios increases from 0.1 percentage points in t=1 to 1.8 percentage points in t=10.

Figure 4 plots multi-period insolvency probabilities for four different initial ages x of insureds.

Figure 4
figure 4

Multi-period insolvency probabilities ψ t , reduced and full correlations structure, different initial ages x.

For all four ages, we again observe higher insolvency probabilities under the full correlation structure, meaning that our results are robust to changes in age. However, there are two noteworthy effects that result from varying the age parameter. First, insolvency probabilities decrease in initial age. This is due to the fact, that for higher ages generally the variation of the number of deaths around the (now higher) mean in relative terms, that is, the variation coefficient is smaller. Second, the increase in insolvency probabilities from switching to the full correlation scenario is greater at higher ages x, except for age x=60. This effect is explained by the different sensitivity of the age-specific death rates to shocks in the mortality index k t , which is controlled by b x (c.p., Eq. (8)). As can be seen in Figure 1, the parameter b x exhibits a hump-shaped profile, peaking around age 50 years. For that reason, we observe a smaller absolute increase in insolvency probability for age x = 60 years in comparison to age x = 50 years.

The effect of different initial insurance portfolio sizes I0 is illustrated in Figure 5.

Figure 5
figure 5

Multi-period insolvency probabilities ψ t , reduced and full correlations structure, different initial numbers of insureds I0.

Not surprisingly, we find that insolvency probabilities are generally higher for smaller portfolios due to a less pronounced risk pooling. However, in relative terms, ignoring the true correlation structure leads to a more severe underestimation of the true insolvency probability for larger portfolios. For example, the relative change in the level of the ten-year insolvency probability amounts to +10.5 per cent for I0 = 5,000 insureds vs. +53.1 per cent for I0=20,000 insureds. This effect can be explained by noting that in small portfolios less unsystematic risk is eliminated compared to large portfolios. By accounting for the full correlation structure, a similar amount of systematic risk (in absolute terms) is added to the risk exposure of both small and large portfolios, leading to a higher relative increase in the overall risk, measured by the insolvency probability, for large portfolios. In other words, for both small and large portfolios the diversification potential decreases, but with more severe consequences for a portfolio originally believed to be well-diversified.

Figure 6 plots multi-period insolvency probabilities for three different fractions γ used when calculating initial equity E0.

Figure 6
figure 6

Multi-period insolvency probability ψ t , reduced and full correlations structure, different equity buffer factors γ.

Insolvency probabilities in Figure 6 are similar, and for similar reasons, to those shown in Figure 5. A higher equity buffer, that is, a higher constant fraction γ of initial premium income raised as equity capital, improves the insurer's solvency situation. Adding, through implementing the full correlation structure, a similar absolute amount of systematic risk on top of the three considered risk exposures leads to a larger relative increase in risk for higher initial amounts of equity capital. In this sense, safer firms, meaning those with greater equity capital, suffer more from the described model risk.

Multi-period insolvency probabilities for different fractions α of assets invested in stocks are plotted in Figure 7.

Figure 7
figure 7

Multi-period insolvency probabilities ψ t , reduced and full correlations structure, different proportions α of assets invested in stocks.

First, Figure 7 again confirms that insolvency probabilities are always higher under the full correlation structure.

Second, we observe some general effects of increasing the proportion of stocks in the asset portfolio. On the one hand, the higher expected return of stocks can lead to reduced insolvency probabilities as assets accumulate more rapidly (compare α=0 with α = 0.1, and α = 0.3 with α = 0.5). On the other hand, the higher volatility of stocks can worsen the insurer's solvency situation (compare α = 0.1 with α = 0.3).

Third, the proportion of stocks influences the difference in insolvency probabilities between the two scenarios, both in absolute and in relative terms. A larger fraction of stocks induces a higher exposure of the insurer to the unfavourable dependency between GDP, assets and mortality, thus liabilities, that was described under Figure 1. Hence, ignoring the full correlation structure results in a more severe underestimation of insolvency probability by insurers heavily invested in stocks.

Conclusion and outlook

Based on demographic findings establishing a link between macroeconomic conditions and mortality, we develop a dynamic asset liability model to assess the impact of macroeconomic fluctuations on the financial stability of a life insurance company. This model allows both assets and liabilities to react to the state of the economy. Stochastic drivers in our model are real GDP, mortality, bond returns and stock returns.

Our simulation results for realistically calibrated model parameters show that multi-period insolvency probabilities are considerably higher when taking into account the dependencies between the mortality index k t in the Lee–Carter model and economic conditions. Thus, ignoring the existing dependency structure will lead an insurer to systematically underestimate its true insolvency probability. This result is robust to variations in the age of insureds, portfolio size, equity base and asset allocation. Through the systematic nature of mortality risk, the relative increase in insolvency probability is higher for insurers with a generally lower insolvency probability. In our model, these are the insurers that have a high equity buffer, relatively mature insureds, and have written a large number of contracts. In addition, the underestimation risk is more severe for insurers heavily invested in stocks, both in absolute and relative terms.

Therefore, the interaction between mortality and macroeconomic conditions needs to be an integral part of life insurers’ internal risk models, of capital allocation decision-making, and of solvency assessment by rating agencies and regulatory authorities. Taking this crucial relationship into consideration will make assessments of an insurer's risk situation more accurate and will thus more effectively protect policy-holders.

The results presented here are obtained within the specific dynamic asset liability model set out in Section “The simulation framework”. Further research could incorporate alternative specifications for model assumptions such as the stochastic mortality model, the asset return process, the modelling of stochastic dependencies and the contract types within the life insurance portfolio held by the insurer. For example, applications of our model could involve investigating a more general insurance portfolio that includes a mixed age structure or annuity contracts. For a mixed age structure, we expect the following: As all age-specific mortality rates react in the same direction to changes in GDP, the resulting effect on insolvency probabilities would be a mixture of the age-specific increases shown in Figure 4. Including annuities, that is, contracts written on the opposite side of mortality risk, would give rise to natural hedging opportunities.Footnote 33 In addition, dependencies between lapse and surrender rates and macroeconomic conditions could be accounted for.Footnote 34 Finally, it should be a promising avenue of research to test empirically how much an insurer's solvency situation (e.g., with the rating as proxy) changes due to shocks to mortality. This could deliver important insights into the question whether investors or rating agencies are aware of the interaction between mortality and macroeconomic conditions and the resulting effect on insurers’ solvency.