Skip to main content
Log in

Interest group survival: Explaining sources of mortality anxiety

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Interest Groups & Advocacy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Executive Summary

In order to engage in public policy, interest groups need to survive and thrive as organizations. What factors shape perceptions of group entrepreneurs as to the future prospects for their groups’ survival? The careful and ambitious work of Gray and Lowery (and others working in the population ecology paradigm) has drawn attention to that fact that not all groups that are born survive. This observation raises the question: what leads groups to ‘feel’ anxiety about their organizational mortality? In their 1997 article, utilizing survey data on the organizational characteristics and situational dynamics of a sample of groups lobbying in several US states, Gray and Lowery asked just that question: what are the levels of ‘mortality anxiety’ among groups still alive? In this article, we revisit this question using similar data, but with some additional variables, and for a non-US case (namely, post-devolution Scottish public policy). In sorting out what factors are associated with anxiety, our analysis seeks to weigh up the existing ecological emphasis on broad shifts in population-level forces (that is, competition) with group-level variables reflecting adaptive changes (that is, identity, uniqueness, changes).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One reviewer reminded us that, in fact, some groups may well not seek to survive: they emerge to fight specific battles or campaigns, accepting success would see the group fold.

  2. We do not investigate the link between mortality anxiety and actual mortality (but see Gray and Lowery, 1997).

  3. These are particularly salient given that Gray and Lowery's work draws explicitly on the ecological thread in organizational studies that has increasingly focused on identity and antecedents in explaining population-level dynamics.

  4. Note that due to our single country research design we cannot measure a variable like population density – Gray and Lowery could do this because they sampled across US states.

  5. Legitimacy is the key mechanism that is said to govern formation, while competition governs subsequent survival prospects as populations grow in number (see Delacroix and Rao (1994) for a sympathetic critique of these as mechanisms of regulation in organizational populations).

  6. We collected data from the 1982–2007 period, but given we survey groups active since 1999, we calculate measures of policy activity from a sub-set of this data. Devolution refers to the period after 1999 in Scotland whereby it was granted its own Parliament with powers to legislate on a limited number of so-called ‘devolved’ issues. The process in the United Kingdom, including powers granted to legislatures in Wales and Northern Ireland is referred to as devolution. Before 1999, the UK Parliament passed legislation relating to Scotland, but there was a Scotland Office that functioned as a Scottish civil service.

  7. Given that Scotland does not have responsibility for all policy matters (so-called reserved matters), our data does not cover policy issues in areas like defense, national security, international trade or foreign affairs.

  8. This data set was compiled largely using paper-based records held in the Scottish Government Library and its document storage facility in Edinburgh, but with the addition of some more recent documentation only available electronically on the Publications pages of the Scottish Government website.

  9. The Scottish Government's internal Consultation Good Practice Guidance (2008) recommends that departments, on completing a consultation exercise, should deposit copies of responses with the Scottish Government Library and also post them on the Scottish Government website. However, this guidance has not always been followed, and therefore not all consultation documentation has made its way into the public domain.

  10. Note that ‘don’t know’ responses are treated as missing in the analysis to follow. This explains the drop in the number of observations in the models presented in this article.

  11. The original coding scheme was developed by Frank Baumgartner and Bryan Jones (see the Policy Agendas coding scheme codebook at www.policyagendas.org). However, we have used the modified UK Policy Agendas codebook at www.policyagendas.org.uk.

  12. In their landmark study of lobbying populations, Gray and Lowery (2000, pp. 97–101) use HHI scores to examine the diversity of the lobbying populations of US states. Following Halpin and Thomas (2012), we also measured this variable according to entropy scores. However, we achieved the same finding, regardless of measure.

  13. Note that we add one to all observations of Paid Staff before taking the natural log to avoid dropping observations with zero paid staff.

  14. Note that a Brant Test indicates that the parallel regression assumption has not been violated, a Link Test indicates that specification error is not present, and that diagnostics of collinearity do not reveal any additional specification problems with the full model. (See full discussion of the diagnostic tests we utilized at www.ats.ucla.edu/stat/stata/dae/ologit.htm.)

  15. Note that in the model estimation the Trade Association group-type is omitted, it is used as the baseline category.

  16. This was regardless of how we calculated the identity index.

References

  • Aldrich, H., Staber, U., Zimmer, C. and Beggs, J.J. (1990) Minimalism and organizational mortality: Patterns of disbanding among U.S. trade associations, 1990–1983. In: J. Singh (ed.), Organizational Evolution. California: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bouwen, P. (2002) Corporate lobbying in the European Union: The logic of access. Journal of European Public Policy 9 (3): 365–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouwen, P. (2004) Exchanging access goods for access. A comparative study of business lobbying in the EU institutions. European Journal of Political Research 43 (3): 337–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browne, W.P. (1990) Organized interests and their issue niche: A search for pluralism in a policy domain. Journal of Politics 52 (2): 477–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, D.A. and Stater, K.J. (2009) Revenue diversification in nonprofit organizations: Does it lead to financial stability? Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 19 (4): 947–966.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, G.R. and Hannan, M.T. (2000) The Demography of Corporations and Industries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delacroix, J. and Rao, A. (1994) Externalities and ecological theory: Unbundling density dependence. In: J. Singh and J. Baum (eds.) Evolutionary Dynamics of Organizations. Oxford, NY: Oxford University Press, pp. 255–268.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V. and Lowery, D. (1996) A niche theory of interest representation. Journal of Politics 58 (1): 91–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V. and Lowery, D. (1997) Life in a niche: Mortality anxiety among organized interests in the American states. Political Research Quarterly 50 (1): 25–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V. and Lowery, D. (2000) The Population Ecology of Interest Representation: Lobbying Communities in the American States, Paperback edn. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagle, T.M. and Mitchell, G.E. (1992) Goodness-of-fit measures for probit and logit. American Journal of Political Science 36 (3): 762–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halpin, D. and Jordan, G. (2009) Interpreting environments: Interest group response to population ecology pressures. British Journal of Political Science 39 (2): 243–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halpin, D. and Binderkrantz, A. (2011) Explaining breadth of policy engagement: Patterns of interest group mobilization in public policy. Journal of European Public Policy 18 (2): 201–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halpin, D. and Jordan, G. (2011) Quantifying Group Populations. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halpin, D. and Nownes, A. (2011) Reappraising the survival question: Why we should focus on interest group ‘Organizational Form’ and ‘Careers’. In: A. Cigler and B. Loomis (eds.) Interest Group Politics, 8th edn. Washington DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halpin, D., Baxter, G. and MacLeod, I. (2012) Multiple Arenas, Multiple Populations. In: D. Halpin and G. Jordan (eds.) Quantifying Group Populations, Chapter 6. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halpin, D. and Thomas III, H.F. (2012) Evaluating the breadth of policy engagement by organized interests. Public Administration, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9299.2011.02005.x.

  • Hanegraaff, M., Braun-Poppelaars, C. and Beyers, J. (2012) The development of the WTO interest group population: Exploring density, stability and diversity over time. In: D. Halpin and G. Jordan (eds.) Quantifying Group Populations, Chapter 8. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, M. and Freeman, J. (1984) Structural inertia and organizational change. American Sociological Review 49 (2): 149–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, M.T. (2005) Ecologies of organizations: Diversity and identity. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19 (1): 51–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaney, M.T. (2004) Outside the issue niche: The multidimensionality of interest group identity. American Politics Research 32 (6): 611–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imig, D. (1992) Resource mobilization and survival tactics of poverty advocacy groups. Western Political Quarterly 45 (2): 501–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordan, G., Halpin, D. and Maloney, W. (2004) Defining interests: Disambiguation and the need for new distinctions. British Journal of Politics and International Relations 6 (2): 195–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordan, G., Baumgartner, F., McCarthy, J., Bevan, S. and Greenan, J. (2011) Tracking interest-group populations in the US and UK. In: D. Halpin and G. Jordan (eds.) Quantifying Group Populations. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jordan, G. and Greenan, J. (2012) The changing contours of British representation: Pluralism in practice. In: D. Halpin and G. Jordan (eds.) Quantifying Group Populations, Chapter 4. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maloney, W.A., Jordan, G. and McLaughlin, A.M. (1994) Interest groups and public policy: The insider/outsider model revisited. Journal of Public Policy 14 (1): 17–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minkoff, D.C. (1999) Bending with the wind: Strategic change and adaptation by women's and racial minority organizations. American Journal of Sociology 104 (6): 1666–1703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minkoff, D., Aisenbrey, S. and Agnone, J. (2008) Organizational diversity in the U.S. advocacy sector. Social Problems 55 (4): 525–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Negro, G., Hannan, M.T. and Rao, H. (2010) Categorical contrast and niche width: Critical success in winemaking. Industrial and Corporate Change 19 (5): 1397–1425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nownes, A.J. (2004) The population ecology of interest group formation: Mobilizing gay and lesbian rights interest groups in the Unites States, 1950–1998. British Journal of Political Science 34 (1): 49–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salisbury, R.H. (1969) An exchange theory of interest groups. Midwest Journal of Political Science 13 (1): 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schattschneider, E.E. (1960) The Semisovereign People: A Realist’s View of Democracy in America. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlozman, K.L. (2010) Who sings in the heavenly chorus? The shape of the organized interest system. In: J. Berry (ed.), The Oxford Handbook of American Political Parties and Interest Groups. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Truman, D.B. (1951/1971) The Governmental Process, 2nd edn. New York: Alfred Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scottish Executive (2008) Consultation Good Practice Guidance. Edinburgh.

  • Walker, J.L. (1991) Mobilizing Interest Groups in America. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Warhurst, J. (1994) The Australian Conservation Foundation: The development of a modern environmental interest group. Environmental Politics 3 (1): 68–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J.Q. (1973/1995) Political Organizations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman, E.W. (1999) The categorical imperative: Securities analysts and the illegitimacy discount. American Journal of Sociology 104 (5): 1398–1438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

Table A1

Table A1 The determinants of interest group mortality anxiety, ordered logit estimation results

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Halpin, D., Thomas, H. Interest group survival: Explaining sources of mortality anxiety. Int Groups Adv 1, 215–238 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1057/iga.2012.11

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/iga.2012.11

Keywords

Navigation