Skip to main content
Log in

The determinants of direct corporate lobbying in the EU: A multi-dimensional proxy of corporate lobbying

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Interest Groups & Advocacy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Executive Summary

This article argues for a more thorough analysis of the dynamics of corporate lobbying within the European Union (EU). Although there is broad consensus among scholars on the emergence of a new type of European lobbying, studies have not sufficiently addressed the underlying economic rationale. Indeed, many authors emphasise the shift towards a system based on direct lobbying; however, these concentre only on systemic and non-economic causes. Direct lobbying dynamics are perceived mainly in two ways: either as a consequence of a conscious political strategy of the European institutions in response to the ‘interest overload’ of the mid-1990s or as a normal phase of the development of interest group populations. Advocating an economics-based analytical approach to European corporate lobbying, this contribution to the debate provides one of the very first attempts to uncover the influence of economic factors on direct corporate lobbying by building on the seminal work proposed by Bernhagen and Mitchell. These authors, very familiar with the American tradition of corporate lobbying studies, were the first to apply a ‘standard model of corporate political behaviour’ to the European context by examining the various determinants of direct lobbying. This article goes further: it analyses the empirical database constructed by Bernhagen and Mitchell, with a multi-dimensional proxy of corporate lobbying. Indeed, the main contribution of this study is in its analysis, namely, the operationalisation of the dependent variable ‘direct lobbying’. It proposes a multi-strategy/multi-venue operationalisation of the dependent variable aiming to overcome the pitfalls that characterise dichotomous and uni-dimensional operational definitions, in order to answer the research question: ‘What are the economic determinants of direct corporate lobbying in the EU?’ Such a multi-dimensional operationalisation of the dependent variable has required the unpacking of some of the elements taken for granted in the discussion on corporate lobbying. This article argues that the researcher needs to take into consideration the various direct lobbying strategies and their relative weights (that is, the multi-strategy operationalisation). For example, accreditation to the EP is not equal to the establishment of a company representation office in Brussels. Furthermore, another possible level of action of a firm's strategy, namely, the industry one, should also be considered (that is, the multi-venue operationalisation): direct lobbying should be analysed as a preference over other lobbying approaches rather than in absolute terms. The findings show how such an expanded operationalisation casts light on the economic determinants of European corporate lobbying. First of all, the Olsonian argument finds empirical support: industry concentration determines lobbying strategies. Second, asset mobility/specificity influences a firm's preference to lobby directly vis-à-vis other venues.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The principal hypotheses, namely, the ones from which explanatory variables will be derived, are labelled as follows: Hypothesis e1, Hypothesis e2, Hypothesis e3 and so on.

  2. The hypotheses from which control variables will be derived are labelled as follows: Hypothesis c1, Hypothesis c2, Hypothesis c3 and so on.

  3. This term was coined in a study on US lobbying in nuclear policy carried out by Baumgartner and Jones (1993). It indicates the framing of an issue in order to adapt it to the most receptive governance level. In European lobbying studies, this term has come predominantly to the fore since the mid-1990s (for example, Baumgartner, 2007; Broscheid and Coen, 2007) and it has been associated with the shift in the access points utilised by interest groups.

  4. This accusation refers to ‘the simple resource-based perspective that ignores critical resource dependencies [and] that it assumes that interest groups are always prepared to modify and Europeanize their strategies as soon as their material self-interests would require or their resources would enable them to do so’ (Beyers and Kerremans, 2007 p. 464 emphasis added).

  5. www.abdn.ac.uk/~pol209/data.htm, accessed 10 August 2011. Information on each variable is available in the Online Appendix 2; www.abdn.ac.uk/~pol209/data.htm, accessed 10 August 2011. I am particularly grateful to Professor Bernhagen, who kindly allowed me to utilise such a data set.

  6. www.forbes.com/2005/03/30/05f2000land.html, accessed 22 August 2011.

  7. For details on the measurement of these variables, consult directly Bernhagen and Mitchell (2009).

  8. www.ec.europa.eu/staffdir/plsql/gsys_page.display_index?pLang=EN, accessed 15 September 2011.

  9. The word ‘strategy’ refers to the manner whereby an actor deploys his/her resources in a practical way within a given venue. For instance, within the venue ‘European direct lobbying’, a firm can appoint a European public affairs representative, establish a company representation office and so on.

  10. The word ‘venue’ is preferred to the word ‘level’ because the former bears a broader meaning not restricted to the categorisation sub-national, national, supra-national (in this case, European).

References

  • Alt, J.E., Carlsen, F., Heum, P. and Johansen, K. (1999) Asset specificity and the political behaviour of firms: Lobbying for subsidies in Norway. International Organization 1 (53): 99–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alt, J.E. and Gilligan, M. (1994) The political economy of trading states. Journal of Political Philosophy 2 (2): 165–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner, F.R. (2007) EU lobbying: A view from the US. Journal of European Public Policy 14 (3): 482–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner, F.R. and Jones, B.D. (1993) Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner, F.R. and Leech, B.L. (1998) Basic Interests: The Importance of Groups in Politics and Political Science. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhagen, P. and Mitchell, N. (2009) The determinants of direct corporate lobbying in the European Union. European Union Politics 10 (2): 155–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beyers, J. and Kerremans, B. (2007) Critical resource dependencies and the Europeanization of domestic interest groups. Journal of European Public Policy 14 (3): 460–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J.N. (ed.) (1982) Adjustment processes and policies: Theoretical issues. In: Import Competition and Response. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Borooah, V. (2004) Logit and Probit: Ordered and Multinomial Models. London: SAGE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Broscheid, A. and Coen, D. (2007) Insider lobbying activity and fora creation in the EU: Empirically exploring the nature of the policy good. Journal of European Public Policy 14 (3): 346–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coen, D. (2007) Empirical and theoretical studies in EU lobbying. Journal of European Public Policy 14 (3): 333–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coen, D. (2009) Business lobbying in the European Union. In: D. Coen and J. Richardson (eds.), Lobbying the European Union: Institutions, Actors and Issues. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coen, D. and Richardson, J. (eds.) (2009) Learning to lobby the European Union: 20 years of change. In: Lobbying the European Union: Institutions, Actors and Issues. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danish Technological Institute. (2008) Job Mobility in the European Union: Optimising its Social and Economic Benefits. Taastrup: Danish Technological Institute, http://www.dti.dk/job-mobility-in-europe/25567.

  • Eising, R. (2007) The access of business interests to EU political institutions: Towards elite pluralism? Journal of European Public Policy 14 (3): 346–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esty, D. and Caves, R.E. (1983) Market structure and political influence: New data on political expenditures, activity and success. Economic Inquiry 21 (1): 24–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. and Stone-Sweet, A. (2002) Constructing polities and markets: An institutionalist account of European integration. American Journal of Sociology 107 (5): 1206–1243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furusawa, T. and Lai, E. (1999) Adjustment costs and gradual trade liberalization. Journal of International Economics 49 (2): 333–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, M. (1997) Lobbying as a private good with intra-industry trade. International Studies Quarterly 41 (3): 455–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godwin, K.R., Lopez, E.J. and Seldon, B.J. (2008) Allocating lobbying resources between collective and private rents. Political Research Quarterly 61 (2): 345–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godwin, K.R. and Seldon, B.J. (2002) What corporations really want from government: The public provision of private goods. In: A. Cigler and B. Loomis (eds.), Interest Group Politics. Washington DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. (2000) Econometric Analysis. Prentice Hall, NJ: Pearson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, W.L., Mitchell, N.J. and Drope, J.M. (2005) The logic of private and collective action. American Journal of Political Science 49 (1): 150–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowery, D. and Gray, V. (2004) A neopluralist perspective on research on organized interests. Political Research Quarterly 57 (1): 163–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowery, D., Poppelaars, C. and Berkhout, J. (2008) The European Union interest system in comparative perspective: A bridge too far? West European Politics 31 (6): 1231–1252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, C. (2004) The power of institutions state and interest group activity in the European Union. European Union Politics 5 (4): 441–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munger, M.C. (1988) On the political participation of the firm in the electoral process: An update. Public Choice 56 (3): 295–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2007) The OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, http://stats.oecd.org/glossary/download.asp.

  • Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ozer, M. and Lee, S. (2009) When do firms prefer individual action to collective action in the pursuit of corporate political strategy? A new perspective on industry concentration. Business and Politics 11 (1): 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogowski, R.L. (1989) Commerce and Coalitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasisht, A.K. (2007) Logit and Probit Analysis. New Delhi: I.A.S.R.I. Technical Report.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Vannoni, M. The determinants of direct corporate lobbying in the EU: A multi-dimensional proxy of corporate lobbying. Int Groups Adv 2, 71–90 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1057/iga.2012.16

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/iga.2012.16

Keywords

Navigation