Skip to main content
Log in

Sudden Financial Arrest

  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

There are striking and terrifying similarities between the sudden failure of a heart and that of a financial system. In the medical literature, the former is referred to as sudden cardiac arrest. By analogy, I refer to its financial counterpart as a sudden financial arrest. In this article I describe the latter and its treatment guided by its medical counterpart.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One way to get a sense of how much the market values the “too-big-to-fail” insurance provided by the government is to compare the cost of funding for small and large banks. Baker and McArthur (2009) compare the average costs of funding for banks with more than $100 billion in assets to the average costs for banks with less than $100 billion. They find that between the first quarter of 2000 and the fourth quarter of 2007, the large banks’ costs were 0.29 percentage points lower than the small banks, averaging across time. Between the fourth quarter of 2008 and the second quarter of 2009, the spread increased to 0.78 percentage points. Clearly, there are many reasons why larger and smaller banks can have different costs of funding: different types of assets, different amounts of leverage, and so on. Baker and McArthur (2009) take the difference between these spreads, 0.78 minus 0.29, as a crude upper-bound on the subsidy associated with the solidification of the “too-big-to-fail” policy after Lehman's collapse. This paper suggests an alternative interpretation: during boom times, the “too-big-to-fail” insurance was there but of little importance, while during the crisis, it became much more important and probably a source of stability.

  2. It turns out that the Bank of America deal was never signed, but the perception that it had been was enough to contain the panic. The U.K. system was less successful in terms of the takers than it would have been socially optimal because it was voluntary and very expensive. Both aspects would be improved by the TICs framework.

  3. For developed economies, the international liquidity shortage problem is much less significant, and it was appropriately dealt with through the swap arrangements between major central banks. These should remain in place, at least on a contingent (to sudden financial arrest) basis. A more delicate problem for these countries stems from the high degree of cross-border interconnectedness of their financial institutions and the potential arbitrage and free-riding issues that may emerge from differences in the type of financial defibrillators available. This raises international coordination issues not developed in this paper, but that obviously need to be addressed.

  4. Haldane (2009) masterfully captures the essence of the counterparty uncertainty problem that can arise in a complex modern financial network, writing that “… knowing your ultimate counterparty's risk then becomes like solving a high-dimension Sudoku puzzle ….”

  5. Michiyo Nakamoto and David Wighton, “Citigroup Chief Stays Bullish on Buy-Outs,” Financial Times, July 9, 2007. Available via the Internet: www.ft.com/cms/s/0/80e2987a-2e50-11dc-821c-0000779fd2ac.html?nclick_check=1.

  6. The new issuance series is the sum over the following categories of asset-backed securities: home equity (subprime); commercial real estate; autos; credit cards; student loans; non-U.S. residential mortgages; and other. The data were provided by Tobias Adrian.

  7. The procedure for estimating this was as follows: For equity, we simply tracked the evolution of each bank's market capitalization, excluding increases in the market cap owing to issues of new shares. For debt, we estimated the duration of each bank's long-term debt (including any preferred shares) from the maturity profiles described in the 10-K statements as of December 2007, assuming the interest rate was equal to the rate on 10-year treasuries plus the spread on five-year CDS for each bank, obtained from JPMorgan. Assuming an unchanged maturity profile, we then tracked the changes in the implied market value of each bank's long-term debt on the basis of the evolution of the CDS spread. The banks included in the calculation are the 19 banks that underwent the “stress tests,” plus Lehman, Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch, Wachovia, and Washington Mutual.

  8. The IMF uses a projection of macroeconomic variables and default rates to estimate losses on loans, and market values to estimate losses on subprime-related securities. To the extent that market prices of securities overreacted due to fire sales, our procedure understates the multiplier.

  9. See Wessel (2009) for a fascinating account of some of the constraints faced by the U.S. Federal Reserve to act quickly during the crisis.

  10. Bob Ivry, Mark Pittman, and Christine Harper, “Sleep-At-Night-Money Lost in Lehman Lesson Missing $63 Billion,” Bloomberg.com, September 8, 2009. Available via the Internet: www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=aLhi.S5xkemY.

  11. James B. Stewart, “Eight Days,” The New Yorker, September 21, 2009.

  12. Ibid., footnote 10.

  13. The Lehman episode highlights the difficulty of predicting the fallout from the resolution of a major financial institution when the possibility of sudden financial arrest is impending. There have been several proposals from academia and policymakers to create mechanisms for orderly resolutions, but resolving a major financial institution, especially during times of panic, inevitably involves an amount of uncertainty that can easily generate catastrophic consequences.

  14. In an October 13, 2008 article in the Wall Street Journal (“Summers Outlines Risks to Recovery”) Alan Krueger, Assistant Secretary for Economic Policy, is quoted as pointing to a near-complete lack of information on such critical variables as hedge fund positions, the interconnections among financial institutions and mortgage-refinancing activity. He argued that “… the economic crisis has given an unintended stress test of our economic and financial indicators.”

  15. See Segoviano and Goodhart (2009) for another interesting attempt to measure banking interconnectedness and stability.

  16. The solvency requirement is nice in theory but a real practical problem during an episode of sudden financial arrest, when the distinction between a solvent and an illiquid institution is highly arbitrary, as most asset prices become uninformative. This turns the Bagehot principle (that is, how regulators determine which firms are insolvent) into yet another source of uncertainty.

  17. See, for example, Caballero (2009a and 2009b), Mehrling and Milne (2008), and Milne (2009) for real-time proposals.

  18. This is a reminder that a taxpayers’ “deal mentality” during a sudden financial arrest episode can be highly counterproductive (Caballero, 2009c). Also, it is important to note that each bank is more likely to know its own financial health and hence be less affected by Knightian uncertainty with respect to its own financial health than are its creditors. For this reason, a bank may reject an expensive insurance deal even when outsiders faced with the same option would accept it.

  19. If there is a concern that TICs will be activated too frequently without sufficient evidence of systemic risk, one could contemplate making activation subject to several “keys,” as with the systemic risk exemption in the FDIC Improvement Act (that is, the president has to sign off, as does two-thirds of the U.S. Federal Reserve board and the FDIC). I owe this example to Morris Goldstein.

  20. Caballero and Kurlat (2009a) argue that TICs would have been an effective policy tool to address the recent crisis. They provide an illustrative example of how these TICs could have been used.

  21. Although European banks also experienced a currency mismatch problem at some stage during the recent crisis, this was expediently solved by a swap mechanism between the Federal Reserve and the ECB. The U.S. Federal Reserve also established dollar liquidity swap lines with the central banks of Australia, Brazil, Canada, Denmark, the United Kingdom (Bank of England), Japan, Korea, Mexico, New Zealand, Norway, Singapore, Sweden, and Switzerland. The swap lines with the ECB and Swiss National Bank were established on December 12, 2007, and the others were established subsequently. In addition, the U.S. Federal Reserve established foreign-currency liquidity swap lines with the Bank of England, ECB, Bank of Japan, and Swiss National Bank should the U.S. Federal Reserve need to borrow foreign currency in the future. A far more problematic issue for these economies is the political concerns that arise from utilizing domestic financial defibrillators when there is significant cross-border interconnectedness among their financial systems. In this context there is a free-rider problem that further delays an already-slow policy response during sudden financial arrest episodes. This coordination problem can be reduced through different international conferences such as the G7 or others, which are the mechanisms used for most other macroeconomic policy coordination issues. This process can be further facilitated by having cross-pledges proportional to these cross-border exposures. That is, the United Kingdom would stand behind a share of the U.S. TICs, were these to be activated, and vice-versa.

  22. See Caballero and Panageas (2007 and 2008) for models and calibrations of the hedging gains for emerging markets subject to sudden stops in net capital inflows and terms-of-trade shocks.

References

  • Abreu, Dilip, and Markus K. Brunnermeier, 2003, “Bubbles and Crashes,” Econometrica, Vol. 71, No. 1, pp. 173–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya, Viral, Lasse Pedersen, Thomas Philippon, and Matthew Richardson, 2009a, “Regulating Systemic Risk,” in Restoring Financial Stability: How to Repair a Failed System, ed. by Viral Acharya and Matthew Richardson (New York, John Wiley and Sons).

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya, Viral, Pedersen, Lasse, Philippon, Thomas, and Richardson, Matthew, 2009b, “Regulating Systemic Risk,” (unpublished; New York, New York University, August).

  • Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin, 2009, “Money, Liquidity, and Monetary Policy,” American Economic Review, Vol. 99, No. 2, pp. 600–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adrian, Tobias, and Markus K. Brunnermeier, 2009, CoVaR, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 348 (August 27).

  • Baker, Dean, and Travis McArthur, 2009, “The Value of the ‘Too Big to Fail’ Big Bank Subsidy,” Center for Economic Policy and Research Issue Brief (September).

  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS), 2009, “Comprehensive Response to the Global Banking Crisis,” BIS press release (September 7). Available via the Internet: www.bis.org/press/p090907.htm.

  • Bernanke, Ben, and Mark Gertler, 1989, “Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations,” American Economic Review, Vol. 79, No. 1, pp. 14–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, Ben, Gertler, Mark, and Simon Gilchrist, 1999, “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework,” in Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. by John Taylor and Michael Woodford (Amsterdam, North Holland).

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio, Claudio, and Mathias Drehmann, 2009, “Assessing the Risk of Banking Crises—Revisited,” BIS Quarterly Review, (March), pp. 29–46. Available Via the Internet: www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt0903.pdf/noframes=1.

  • Broner, Fernando, Guido Lorenzoni, and Sergio Schmukler, 2008, “Why Do Emerging Economies Borrow Short Term?,” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, October).

  • Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Lasse Heje Pedersen, 2009a, “Market Liquidity and Funding Liquidity,” Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 22, No. 6, pp. 2201–2238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Pedersen, Lasse Heje, 2009b, “Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007–08,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23, No. 1, pp. 77–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., 2003, “The Future of the IMF,” American Economic Review, Vol. 93, No. 2, pp. 31–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., 2009a, “Dow Boost and a (Nearly) Private Sector Solution to the Crisis,” VOX, February 22. Available via the Internet: www.voxeu.com/index.php?q=node/3112.

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., 2009b, “A Global Perspective on the Great Financial Insurance Run: Causes, Consequences, and Solutions,” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, January 20).

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., 2009c, “A Deal Mentality is Bad Economics,” VOX, March 5. Available via the Internet: www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3196January.

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Alp Simsek, 2009a, “Complexity and Financial Panics,” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, June 17).

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Simsek, Alp, 2009b, “Fire Sales in a Model of Complexity,” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, October 28).

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Arvind Krishnamurthy, 2001, “International Domestic Collateral Constraints in a Model of Emerging Market Crises,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 48, No. 3, pp. 513–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Krishnamurthy, Arvind, 2006, “Bubbles and Capital Flow Volatility: Causes and Risk Management,” Journal Monetary of Economics, Vol. 53, No. 1, pp. 35–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Krishnamurthy, Arvind, 2008a, “Collective Risk Management in a Flight to Quality Episode,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 63, No. 5, pp. 2195–2230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Krishnamurthy, Arvind, 2008b, “Knightian Uncertainty and its Implications for the TARP,” Financial Times Economists’ Forum, November 24. Available via the Internet: www.blogs.ft.com/economistsforum/2008/11/knightian-uncertainty-and-its-implications-for-the-tarp/.

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Pablo Kurlat, 2009a, “The ‘Surprising’ Origin and Nature of Financial Crises: A Macroeconomic Policy Proposal,” paper prepared for the Jackson Hole Symposium on Financial Stability and Macroeconomic Policy, August.

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Kurlat, Pablo, 2009b, “Public-Private Partnerships for Liquidity Provision,” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, March 4).

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Stavros Panageas, 2007, “A Global Equilibrium Model of Sudden Stops and External Liquidity Management,” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, September 7).

  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Panageas, Stavros, 2008, “Hedging Sudden Stops and Precautionary Contractions,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 85, pp. 28–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplin, Andrew, and John Leahy, 1994, “Business as Usual, Market Crashes and Wisdom after the Fact,” American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 3, pp. 548–565.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caruana, Jaime, 2009, “Deposit Insurance Core Principles,” keynote address at the conference on “Core Principles for Effective Deposit Insurance Systems,” Bank for International Settlements, Basel, September 23–24.

  • Coval, Joshua, and Erik Stafford, 2007, “Asset Fire Sales (and Purchases) in Equity Markets,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 86, No. 2, pp. 479–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flannery, Mark, 2005, “No Pain, No Gain? Effecting Market Discipline via ‘Reverse Convertible Debentures’,” in Capital Adequacy beyond Basel: Banking, Securities, and Insurance, ed. by Hal S. Scott (Oxford, UK, Oxford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Geanakoplos, John, 2003, “Liquidity, Default, and Crashes: Endogenous Contracts in General Equilibrium,” in Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Eighth World Conference, Econometric Society Monographs, Vol. 2, ed. by Dewatripont, Mathias, Lars, Peter Hausen, and Stephen J. Tuenolsky (Cambridge University Press).

  • Geanakoplos, John, 2009, “The Leverage Cycle,” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper 1715R (New Haven, Connecticut, Yale University).

  • Geanakoplos, John, and Ana Fostel, 2008, “Leverage Cycles and the Anxious Economy,” American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 4, pp. 1211–1244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, Gary B., and Metrick Andrew, 2009a, “Haircuts,” NBER Working Paper 15273.

  • Gorton, Gary B., and Andrew, Metrick, 2009b, “Securtized Banking and the Run on Repo,” Working Paper, Yale School of Management.

  • Haldane, Andrew G., 2009, “Rethinking the Financial Network,” speech to the Financial Student Association, Amsterdam, April.

  • Hart, Oliver, and Luigi Zingales, 2009, “A New Capital Regulation for Large Financial Institutions,” CEPR Discussion Paper 7298 (London, Centre for Economic Policy Research).

  • Holmström, Bengt, and Jean Tirole, 1998, “Private and Public Supply of Liquidity,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2009, Global Financial Stability Report, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington, October).

  • Kashyap, Anil K., Raghuram G. Rajan, and Jeremy C. Stein, 2008, “Rethinking Capital Regulation,” in Maintaining Stability in a Changing Financial System, Paper prepared for Federal Revenue Bank of Kansas City Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 21–23 August.

  • Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and John Moore, 1997, “Credit Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 105, No. 2, pp. 211–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling, Perry, and Alistair Milne, 2008, “Government's Role as Credit Insurer of Last Resort and How It Can be Fulfilled,” (unpublished, October 9). Barnard College and Cass Business School.

  • Milne, Alistair, 2009, The Fall of the House of Credit (Cambridge, UK, and New York, Cambridge University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, Mark, Lasse Heje Pedersen, and Todd Pulvino, 2007, “Slow Moving Capital,” American Economic Review, Vol. 97, No. 2, pp. 215–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pulvino, Todd C., 1998, “Do Asset Fire Sales Exist? An Empirical Investigation of Commercial Aircraft Transactions,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 53, No. 3, pp. 939–978.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, Carmen, and Vincent Reinhart, 2008, “Capital Flow Bonanzas: An Encompassing View of the Past and Present,” NBER Working Paper 14321 (Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research).

  • Segoviano, Miguel, and Charles Goodhart, 2009, “Banking Stability Measures,” IMF Working Paper 09/4 (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

  • Squam Lake Working Group on Financial Regulation, 2009, “An Expedited Resolution Mechanism for Distressed Financial Firms: Regulatory Hybrid Securities,” Council on Foreign Relations Center for Geoeconomic Studies Working Paper, April (New York, Council on Foreign Relations). Available via the Internet: www.cfr.org/publication/19002/expedited_resolution_mechanism_for_distressed_financial_firms.html.

  • Swagel, Phillip, 2009, “The Financial Crisis: An Inside View,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring (Washington, The Brookings Institution).

  • U.S. Treasury, 2009, “Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation,” U.S. Department of the Treasury White Paper. Available via the Internet: www.treasury.gov/initiatives/regulatoryreform/.

  • Wessel, David, 2009, In Fed We Trust (New York, Crown Publishing Group).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Additional information

*Ricardo J. Caballero is Chairman of the Department of Economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. This paper was presented as the Mundell-Fleming Lecture at the Tenth Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference at the International Monetary Fund in Washington held November 5–6, 2009. The author thanks Viral Acharya, Olivier Blanchard, Morris Goldstein, Bengt Holmström, Pablo Kurlat, Juan Ocampo, and conference participants for their comments, as well as Jonathan Goldberg for outstanding research assistance.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Caballero, R. Sudden Financial Arrest. IMF Econ Rev 58, 6–36 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2010.1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2010.1

JEL Classifications

Navigation