Skip to main content
Log in

Information technology and transnational integration: Theory and evidence on the evolution of the modern multinational enterprise

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Reflecting amplified hazards in cross-border exchange and imperfections in markets for intangibles, internalization has been central in multinational enterprise (MNE) theory. This centrality notwithstanding, the fact is that internalization coheres with lower-powered incentives and carries an implicit drawback, namely, higher realized production costs. With the emergence and deployment of information and communication technology (ICT), modern MNEs are reshaping their transnational governance to address this cost. The modern MNE uses ICT to mitigate transaction costs, and evolves more to arm's length exchange to incentivize lower production costs. A testable prediction is that MNEs in industries more susceptible to and employing more ICT will exhibit a reduced propensity for transnational integration. We examine this hypothesis using available data from 1982 to 1997 for US MNEs across all manufacturing sectors. Regression results and robustness tests are strongly congruent with the prediction. This study, a first to explore empirically the role of ICT in the evolution of transnational exchange, suggests that MNE theory, until now founded primarily on transaction cost economics and a cross-border control theory of value capture, is more likely to keep pace with developments in MNE practice by opening up to incentive theories of exchange governance and a cross-border coordination theory of value creation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As described in Dunning (1980), the O refers to firm-specific capabilities, including those in research, marketing, and managing; the L refers to location-specific factors, especially pertaining to the destination of foreign direct investment; and the I refers to the relative benefits of internalization.

  2. Separately, even where asset specificity remains high (because, say, it creates net value), the cost of achieving that specificity can decline markedly because of ICT. An illustration from Argyres (1999) is illuminating. Compared with client-specific prototyping performed manually by engineers employing traditional methods, the cost of computer-aided design and prototyping, equally client specific, is reduced, measured in terms of time and material investment, by an order of magnitude. In turn, the consequence of holdup in the same transaction is less daunting. It is much more difficult to be held up when the investment at risk is not large. This is to clarify that what matters is not asset specificity per se as much as the cost of asset specificity, which has also tended to decline owing to the development and deployment of ICT. This effect, too, is compatible with the model and logic outlined in Riordan and Williamson (1985).

  3. The 15 two-digit industries covered are: food and beverages; chemicals and drugs; primary metals; fabricated metals; machinery; electrical and electronic equipment; motor vehicles; other transport (mainly aircraft); textile products and apparel; lumber, wood, and furniture; paper and allied products; printing and publishing; rubber and miscellaneous plastics; glass, stone, clay, and nonmetallic mineral products; and instruments and related products.

  4. While some existing studies focus only on capital equipment (i.e., hardware), we include software, maintenance, and service expenditures, because the deployment and maintenance of software (e.g., billing systems, supply chain, and customer management) will affect the actual ability of firms to coordinate within and across organizational boundaries. Specifically, we use the following 15 ICT-related investment categories reported in BEA data: mainframe computers; personal computers; direct access storage devices; computer printers; computer terminals; computer tape drives; computer storage devices; integrated systems; prepackaged software; custom software; own-account software; communication equipment; instruments; photocopy and related equipment; and office and accounting equipment. In supplementary analysis, wherein we used only the last category, office and accounting equipment, as in Brynjolfsson et al. (1994) we found no sign reversals in any of the variables of interest.

  5. We follow Blonigen (2001) here in using US MNEs’ foreign to total employment ratio to proxy importance of international operations. This ratio is not only a good indicator of the “extent of multinationality” that Dunning and others proposed would increase transnational integration (see e.g., Siddharthan & Kumar, 1990), but also, unlike alternatives based on sales figures, it does not pose problems related to exchange rate and other nominal-to-real conversions.

  6. We also included an alternative operationalization of import competition wherein the numerator excludes intrafirm imports. Under this alternative specification, results were unchanged.

  7. Destination-specific data are not available for MNE intrafirm trade at the level of aggregation we are interested in. For our measurement purposes, developing countries include all countries except Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom.

  8. To cross-validate, we re-estimated all models by including year fixed effects. In these regressions, echoing the results of the above-mentioned pooling tests, when included, none of the year dummies was significant (separately or jointly), and, importantly, the inclusion of year fixed effects did not affect the sign or significance of any right-hand-side variable.

  9. To further establish the robustness of the results to potential simultaneity problem, we ran our regressions including a lagged DV on the right-hand side (see Greve & Goldeng, 2004). While inclusion of the lagged DV, which itself was highly significant, rendered some control variables insignificant, ICT investment intensity coefficient was still negative and statistically significant.

  10. As the dependent variable in this first stage, ICT investment intensity, is measured at the US (and not at MNE parent) level by industry, we accordingly measure knowledge intensity as US firms’ R&D spending as a percentage of their total sales, and MNE intensity as the percentage of US employees working for US multinational parents.

  11. Baker and Hubbard's (2004) study of the use of on-board computers for fleet usage optimization in the trucking industry is in this same spirit of superior capital “exploitation.”

  12. Zero-order correlations for computation power, total investment, and capital intensity are 0.32, 0.68, and 0.45, respectively, with the instrumented variable (ICT investment intensity), as opposed to 0.04, 0.35, and 0.19 with the error term.

  13. Three observations about the results of the first-stage regressions are in order (see appendix Table C1). First, all three instruments are significant, and, as expected, positively signed. (Given that computation power does not vary by industry, it is quite an indication that this variable is even moderately significant.) Second, most control variables (especially knowledge intensity) also have a statistically significant impact on ICT investment intensity. Finally, industry-fixed effects (not shown) tend to be significant, and account in good measure for the high overall R2.

  14. To check further, in supplementary regressions (not shown here), we included a three-way interaction term with ICT investment intensity, knowledge intensity, and internationalization. This three-way interaction term was positive and highly significant (but did not affect the sign and significance of other variables). This suggests that the two-way interaction of ICT investment intensity and knowledge intensity changes for the levels of the third factor, internationalization. More clearly, the ICT investment intensity × knowledge intensity interaction is less negative and more positive (in the direction hypothesized), the higher the internationalization of the industry.

  15. We also checked for a potential moderation effect of time trend on the ICT investment intensity – MNE transnational integration link. It has been suggested that complementary investments in new organizational processes (re-engineering) and in application software are necessary to derive the full benefits of ICT (Brynjolfsson & Hitt, 1996), and complementary “ecosystem” ICT investments by exchange partners are expected to boost the impact of ICT. Expecting that such complementary developments occurred gradually over the 1980s and 1990s, and given that processes and routines that are initially tacit become more explicit over time (Kogut & Zander, 1993), one might expect the effect of ICT investment intensity on MNE transnational integration to have increased over time. There was statistical support for this prediction too.

References

  • Antras, P. 2005. Property rights and the international organization of production. American Economic Review, 95 (2): 25–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argyres, N. S. 1999. The impact of information technology on coordination: Evidence from the B-2 “stealth” bomber. Organization Science, 10 (2): 162–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker, G. P., & Hubbard, T. N. 2003. Make versus buy in trucking: Asset ownership, job design, and information. American Economic Review, 93 (3): 551–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker, G. P., & Hubbard, T. N. 2004. Contractibility and asset ownership: On-board computers and governance in US trucking. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119 (4): 1443–1479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi, B. 1986. Pooling under misspecification: Some Monte Carlo evidence on the Kmenta and the error components techniques. Econometric Theory, 2 (3): 429–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi, B. 2001. Econometric analysis of panel data, (2nd ed.). New York: John Wiley & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartel, A., Ichniowski, C., & Shaw, K. 2007. How does information technology affect productivity? Plant-level comparisons of product innovation, process improvement, and worker skills. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (4): 1721–1758.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartlett, M. S. 1947. The use of transformations. Biometrics, 3 (1): 39–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N., & Katz, J. N. 1995. What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section data. American Political Science Review, 89 (3): 634–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belorgey, N., Lecat, R., & Maury, T.-P. 2006. Determinants of productivity per employee: An empirical estimation using panel data. Economics Letters, 91 (2): 153–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen, B. A. 2001. In search of substitution between foreign production and exports. Journal of International Economics, 53 (1): 81–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, N., Garicano, L., Sadun, R., & Van Reenen, J. 2009. The distinct effects of information technology and communication technology on firm organization. Working Paper No. 14975, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Brainard, S. L. 1997. An empirical assessment of the proximity-concentration trade-off between multinational sales and trade. American Economic Review, 87 (4): 520–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson, E. 1994. Information assets, technology, and organization. Management Science, 40 (12): 1645–1662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. M. 1996. Paradox lost? Firm-level evidence on the returns to information systems spending. Management Science, 42 (4): 541–558.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson, E., Malone, T. W., Gurbaxani, V., & Kambil, A. 1994. Does information technology lead to smaller firms? Management Science, 40 (12): 1628–1644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. 1985. The economic theory of the multinational enterprise. New York: St Martin’s Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Campa, J. M., & Guillén, M. F. 1999. The internalization of exports: Firm- and location-specific factors in a middle-income country. Management Science, 45 (11): 1463–1478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R. E. 1996. Multinational enterprise and economic analysis, (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesbrough, H. W. 2003. The era of open innovation. Sloan Management Review, 44 (3): 35–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cho, K. R. 1990. The role of product-specific factors in intra-firm trade of US manufacturing multinational corporations. Journal of International Business Studies, 21 (2): 319–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, 4 (16): 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Commons, J. R. 1932. The problem of correlating law, economics, and ethics. Wisconsin Law Review, 8: 3–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dedrick, J., & Kraemer, K. L. 2005. The impacts of IT on firm and industry structure: The personal computer industry. California Management Review, 47 (3): 122–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denis, D. J., Denis, D. K., & Yost, K. 2002. Global diversification, industrial diversification, and firm value. Journal of Finance, 57 (5): 1951–1979.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M. A., Foley, C. F., & Hines, J. R. 2004. A multinational perspective on capital structure choice and internal capital markets. Journal of Finance, 59 (6): 2451–2487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H. 1980. Toward an eclectic theory of international production: Some empirical tests. Journal of International Business Studies, 11 (1): 9–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H. 1993. Multinational enterprises and the global economy. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ethier, W. J. 1986. The multinational firm. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101 (4): 805–833.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C. 1998. Integration of trade and disintegration of production in the global economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12 (4): 31–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C. 2000. World trade flows, 1980–1997. Davis, CA: Institute of Governmental Affairs, University of California.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gertner, R. H. 2001. Explaining vertical integration practices, Working Paper, University of Chicago.

  • Gibbons, R. 2005. Four formal(izable) theories of the firm? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 58 (2): 200–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greve, H. R., & Goldeng, E. 2004. Longitudinal analysis in strategic management research. In D. Ketchen & D. Bergh (Eds.), Research methods in strategy and management, Vol. 1: 35–163. New York: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S., & Hart, O. 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of lateral and vertical integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94 (4): 691–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurbaxani, V., & Whang, S. 1991. The impact of information systems on organizations and markets. Communications of the ACM, 34 (1): 59–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, G. H., Mataloni, R. J., & Slaughter, M. J. 2001. Expansion strategies of US multinational firms. Working Paper No. 8433, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Hart, O., & Moore, J. 1990. Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 98 (6): 1119–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head, K., & Ries, J. 2001. Overseas investments and firm exports. Review of International Economics, 9 (1): 108–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. J. 2000. The institutional environment for multinational investment. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 16 (2): 334–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. J., & Williamson, O. E. 1999. Comparative economic organization: Within and between countries. Business and Politics, 1 (3): 261–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennart, J.-F. 1982. A theory of multinational enterprise. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hipple, F. S. 1990. The measurement of international trade related to multinational companies. American Economic Review, 80 (5): 1263–1270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. 1994. The firm as an incentive system. American Economic Review, 84 (4): 972–991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hymer, S. H. 1976. The international operations of national firms: A study of direct foreign investment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, J., & DiNardo, J. 1997. Econometric methods. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W. 2001. Information technology and the US economy. American Economic Review, 91 (1): 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy, P. 2003. A guide to econometrics, (5th ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, S. 1999. High-powered incentives vs low-powered incentives: Why low-powered incentives within firms? Seoul Journal of Economics, 12 (1): 27–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kobrin, S. 1991. An empirical analysis of the determinants of global integration. Strategic Management Journal, 12 (Summer Special Issue): 17–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B. 1985. Designing global strategies: Comparative and competitive value-added chains. Sloan Management Review, 26 (4): 15–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1993. Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies, 24 (4): 625–645.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lall, S. 1978. The pattern of intra-firm exports by US multinationals. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 40 (3): 209–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lall, S. 1980. Monopolistic advantages and foreign involvement by US manufacturing industry. Oxford Economic Papers, 32 (1): 102–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, R. Z., & Slaughter, M. J. 1993. International trade and American wages in the 1980s: Giant sucking sound or small hiccup? In M. N. Baily & C. Winston (Eds.), Brookings papers on economic activity: Microeconomics: 161–210. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, J. R. 1995. The boundaries of multinational enterprises and the theory of international trade. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9 (2): 169–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, X., & Salomon, R. M. 2003. Knowledge transfer capacity and its implications for the theory of the multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies, 34 (4): 356–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, K. J., & Salomon, R. M. 2006. Capabilities, contractual hazards, and governance: Integrating resource-based and transaction cost perspectives. Academy of Management Journal, 49 (5): 942–959.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLaren, J. 2000. Globalization and vertical structure. American Economic Review, 90 (5): 1239–1354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. 1992. Economics, organization & management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morck, R., & Yeung, B. 1991. Why investors value multinationality. Journal of World Business, 64 (2): 165–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Motohashi, K. 1997. ICT diffusion and its economic impact in OECD countries. OECD Science Technology and Industry Review, 20 (Special Issue): 13–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray, M. P. 2006. Avoiding invalid instruments and coping with weak instruments. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20 (4): 111–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nachum, L., & Zaheer, S. 2005. The persistence of distance? The impact of technology on MNE motivations for foreign investment. Strategic Management Journal, 26 (8): 747–767.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nevo, N., & Rosen, A.M. 2008. Identification with imperfect instruments. Working Paper No. 14434, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Nohria, N., & Ghoshal, S. 1997. The differentiated network: Organizing multinational corporations for value creation. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palmisano, S. J. 2006. The globally integrated enterprise. Foreign Affairs, 85 (3): 127–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, W. 2003. Whither investment? Speech delivered at Missouri Valley Economics Association, St Louis, Missouri, 28 February 2003, http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/historicaldocs/wp/, Accessed 2 October 2009.

  • Porter, M. E. 1986. Competition in global industries: A conceptual framework. In M. E. Porter (Ed.), Competition in global industries: 15–60. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. E. 1990. The competitive advantage of nations. New York: The Free Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Riordan, M., & Williamson, O. E. 1985. Asset specify and economic organization. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 3 (4): 365–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, D. J., & Van den Steen, E. 2000. Shareholder interests, human capital investment and corporate governance. Stanford GSB Research Paper 1631.

  • Rugman, A. 1980. Internalization as a general theory of foreign direct investment: A re-appraisal of the literature. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 116 (2): 365–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siddharthan, N. S., & Kumar, N. 1990. The determinants of inter-industry variations in the proportion of intra-firm trade: The behavior of US multinationals. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 126 (3): 581–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. 1982. Models of bounded rationality: Behavioral economics and business organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vernon, R. 1971. Sovereignty at bay: The multinational spread of US enterprises. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1991. Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36 (2): 269–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 2005. The economics of governance. American Economic Review, 95 (2): 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Withington, F. G. 1997. The resurgence of the mainframe computer. Spectrum, 93: 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zenger, T. R., & Hesterly, W. S. 1997. The disaggregation of corporations: Selective intervention, high-powered incentives, and molecular units. Organization Science, 8 (3): 209–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

For helpful comments during the development of this paper we thank Ron Adner, William Alterman, Gareth Dyas, Antonio Fatas, Javier Gimeno, Dominique Heau, Tarun Khanna, Bruce Kogut, Robert Lawrence, Christoph Loch, Catherine Mann, Ilian Mihov, Tomasz Obloj, James Rauch, Jeffrey Reuer, Daniel Sichel, Vanessa Strauss-Kahn, Timothy Van Zandt, Oliver Williamson, and Enver Yucesan; and Vit Henisz and three anonymous JIBS reviewers. We are grateful to the US Bureau of Labor Statistics and INSEAD for financial support of this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Subramanian Rangan.

Additional information

Accepted by Witold Henisz, Area Editor, 18 June 2009. This paper has been with the authors for three revisions.

Appendices

Appendix A

Table A1

Table A1 US MNEs’ transnational integration ratios, by industry, selected years between 1982 and 1997 (percentages)

Appendix B

Table B1

Table B1 US information and communication technology (ICT) investment per employee, by industry, selected years between 1982 and 1997

Appendix C

Table C1

Table C1 First-stage regression explaining ICT investment intensity, 1982–1997

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Rangan, S., Sengul, M. Information technology and transnational integration: Theory and evidence on the evolution of the modern multinational enterprise. J Int Bus Stud 40, 1496–1514 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2009.55

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2009.55

Keywords

Navigation