Skip to main content
Log in

Cross-border mergers and domestic-firm wages: Integrating “spillover effects” and “bargaining effects”

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Two literatures exist concerning cross-border merger activity’s impact on domestic wages: one focusing on positive spillover effects; the other focusing on negative bargaining effects. Motivated by scarce theoretical scholarship spanning these literatures, we nest both mechanisms in a single conceptual framework. Considering the separate phenomena of inward and outward cross-border merger activity, our theoretical model generates three formal propositions: cross-border mergers can lead to wage increases via positive spillover effects; and negative bargaining effects are relatively more dominant when union market power is high, and when merging firms exhibit relatedness. Employing US firm-level panel data on wages combined with industry-level data on unionization and merger activity (covering 1989–2001), we find support for our propositions as inward and outward cross-border merger activity generate positive spillovers to wages, but are more likely to generate firm-level wage decreases when unionization rates are high and when cross-border merger activity is characterized as horizontal. Accordingly, future research on how cross-border mergers affect domestic wages should be mindful that both spillover and bargaining effects are at play, and that the degree of union market power and the relatedness of cross-border merger activity are critical in determining which effect dominates.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Works formalizing the spillover mechanism include: Wang and Blomström (1992), Fosfuri, Motta, and Rønde (2001), Glass and Saggi (2002), Grünfeld (2006), Lin and Saggi (2007), and Markusen and Trofimenko (2009).

  2. The model is largely influenced by Lommerud et al. (2006), although in contrast to that model we focus on how spillover and bargaining effects impact domestic-outsider firm wages.

  3. Other cross-border combinations of firms exist that lead to similar results. Lommerud et al. (2006) allow for two cross-border M&As and find results consistent with ours, as a second cross-border M&A in the absence of spillovers leads to even greater downward pressures on wages, but they do not model externality-based spillovers.

  4. We treat spillovers – measured by μ – as exogenous, but the externality-based spillover effects process is modeled in Fosfuri et al. (2001) and Glass and Saggi (2002). In particular, they model the interaction in the labor market between the workers and the firm after technology has been transferred via a cross-border merger.

  5. While the mechanism we focus on for negative bargaining effects to domestic-outsider firms is valid, it is not necessarily the only mechanism behind our empirical findings. In particular, a “threat effect” may also be present, as the establishment of production sites in foreign countries by domestic-insider firms may provide enhanced bargaining power for domestic-outsider firms, as they can more credibly threaten to move production abroad after these concrete actions have been taken by industry competitors (Mezetti & Dinopoulos, 1991). Yet we should underscore that such a mechanism resides outside our modeling approach.

  6. This follows straightforward from our assumptions that a>c and 0<b<1.

  7. Such a downward pressure on wages will not be present in a corresponding model with a competitive labor market with a horizontal supply curve (a constant reservation wage). Furthermore, Lommerud et al. (2005) model bargaining effects via a monopoly union setting wages (like we do here) and also via a situation where domestic-industry wages are set through bargaining. Most importantly, they find identical qualitative results when considering the impact of cross-border mergers on wages under both approaches.

  8. Any uncontrolled-for demand effects from cross-border merger activity that reside outside the error term will be captured by the inward-share and outward-share variables, thus reducing the size of the coefficient estimates for these variables meant to capture positive spillover effects.

  9. The average unionization rates for each of our 36 two-digit SIC industries are: Metal Mining 31%; Coal Mining 30%; Oil & Gas Extraction 3%; Food & Kindred Products 20%; Textile Mill Products 5%; Lumber & Wood Products 7%; Furniture & Fixtures 8%; Paper & Allied Products 31%; Printing/Publishing 8%; Chemicals 10%; Petroleum Refining 24%; Rubber Products 16%; Stone, Clay, Glass & Concrete 19%; Primary Metal 32%; Fabricated Metal 15%; Industrial & Commercial Machinery 11%; Electronic & Electrical Equipment 9%; Measuring & Analyzing Instruments 5%; Misc. Manufacturing 7%; Local & Highway Transit 35%; Motor Freight & Warehouse 20%; Water Transport 24%; Air Transport 38%; Pipelines 19%; Transport Services 7%; Communications 23%; Electric Gas & Sanitary Services 31%; Depository Institutions 1%; Non-depository Credit Institutions 1%; Hotels 10%; Personal Services 3%; Business Services 3%; Auto Repair & Parking 3%; Health Services 10%; Educational Services 35%; Social Services 7%. Accordingly, the average unionization rate for the 36 industries ranges from 1 to 38% (and the annual measures range from 0.34 to 41.0%), thus indicating plenty of variation in this measure.

  10. Data do not extend beyond 2001 due to the switch from SIC to North American Industry Classification System classification. An attempt to bridge these industry classifications found the correspondence tables to be quite imperfect at this level of analysis.

  11. Unreported empirical tests suggest that the lack of robustness for inward-based bargaining effects may be due to low value-added firms where inward-based bargaining effects (and spillover effects) appear to be minimal.

  12. In results available upon request, we engage in a theoretical exercise akin to that of Pagel and Wey (2013) where we show our theoretical propositions concerning negative bargaining effects to be robust when we layer-on additional firm heterogeneity in the form of low-cost and high-cost firms.

References

  • Aitken, B. J., & Harrison, A. E. 1999. Do domestic firms benefit from direct foreign investment? Evidence from Venezuela. American Economic Review, 89 (3): 605–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aitken, B. J., Harrison, A. E., & Lipsey, R. E. 1996. Wages and foreign ownership: A comparative study of Mexico, Venezuela and the United States. Journal of International Economics, 40 (3–4): 345–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, M., Bellman, L., Schank, T., & Upward, R. 2009. The takeover and selection effects of foreign-owned establishments: An analysis using linked employer-employee data. Review of World Economics, 145 (2): 293–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashenfelter, O., & Johnson, G. E. 1972. Unionism, relative wages and labor quality in US manufacturing industries. International Economic Review, 13 (3): 488–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balsvik, R. 2011. Is labor mobility a channel for spillovers from multinationals? Evidence from Norwegian manufacturing. Review of Economics and Statistics, 93 (1): 285–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braun, S. 2008. Should trade unions welcome foreign investors? Evidence from Danish matched employer–employee data. Discussion Paper No. 7, Centre for Economic and Business Research (CEBR).

  • Braun, S., & Scheffel, J. 2007. Does international outsourcing depress union wages? Working Paper No. 2007-033, SFB TR-649.

  • Buckley, P. J., & Ghauri, P. N. 2004. Globalization, economic geography and the strategy of multinational enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies, 35 (2): 81–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. J., Clegg, J., & Wang, C. 2007. Is the relationship between inward FDI and spillover effects linear? An empirical examination of the case of China. Journal of International Business Studies, 38 (3): 447–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J. 1993. Technological competence and evolving patterns of international production. In H. Cox, J. Clegg, & G. Ietto-Giles (Eds), The growth of global business: 19–37. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J. 1995. The globalisation of technology: What remains of the product life cycle model. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19 (1): 155–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J., & Mudambi, R. 2005. MNE competence-creating subsidiary mandates. Strategic Management Journal, 26 (12): 1109–1128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantwell, J., & Mudambi, R. 2011. Physical attraction and the geography of knowledge sourcing in multinational enterprises. Global Strategy Journal, 1 (3–4): 206–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R. E. 1996. Multinational enterprise and economic analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, M. 2001. Threat effect of foreign direct investment on labor union wage premium. Working Paper No. 27, Political Economy Research Institute (PERI).

  • Conyon, M. J., Girma, S., Thompson, S., & Wright, P. W. 2002. The productivity and wage effects of foreign acquisition in the United Kingdom. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 50 (1): 85–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M. A., Foley, C. F., & Hines, J. R. 2009. Domestic effects of the foreign activities of US multinationals. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1 (1): 181–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickens, W. T., & Katz, L. F. 1987. Inter-industry wage differences and industry characteristics. In K. Lang, & J.S. Leonard (Eds), Unemployment and the structure of labor markets: 48–89. New York: Basil Blackwell Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Driffield, N. 1996. Global competition and the labour market. Reading, MA: Harwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H. 1981. International production and the multinational enterprise. London, UK: George Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C., & Egger, H. 2009. Wage bargaining and multinational firms. Journal of International Economics, 77 (2): 206–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eden, L., & Lenway, S. 2001. Introduction to the symposium multinationals: The Janus face of globalization. Journal of International Business Studies, 32 (3): 383–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fabbri, F., Haskel, J. E., & Slaughter, M. J. 2003. Does nationality of ownership matter for labor demands? Journal of the European Economic Association, 1 (2–3): 698–707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feinberg, S. E., & Majumdar, S. K. 2001. Technology spillovers from foreign direct investment in the Indian pharmaceutical industry. Journal of International Business Studies, 32 (3): 421–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Figlio, D. N., & Blonigen, B. A. 2000. The effects of foreign direct investment on local communities. Journal of Urban Economics, 48 (2): 338–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fosfuri, A., & Motta, M. 1999. Multinationals without advantages. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 101 (4): 617–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fosfuri, A., Motta, M., & Rønde, T. 2001. Foreign direct investment and spillovers through workers’ mobility. Journal of International Economics, 53 (1): 205–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaston, N., & Nelson, D. 2002. Integration, foreign direct investment and labour markets: Microeconomic perspectives. The Manchester School, 70 (3): 420–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma, S., Greenaway, D., & Wakelin, K. 2001. Who benefits from foreign direct investment in the UK? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 48 (2): 119–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass, A. J., & Saggi, K. 2002. Multinational firms and technology transfer. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 104 (4): 495–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffith, R., Harrison, R., & Van Reenen, J. 2006. How special is the special relationship? Using the impact of US R&D spillovers on UK firms as a test of technology sourcing. The American Economic Review, 96 (5): 1859–1875.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grünfeld, L. 2006. Multinational production, absorptive capacity, and endogenous R&D spillovers. Review of International Economics, 14 (5): 922–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg, A. J., & Greenaway, D. 2004. Much ado about nothing? Do domestic firms really benefit from foreign direct investment? The World Bank Research Observer, 19 (2): 171–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg, A. J., & Strobl, E. 2005. Spillovers from foreign firms through worker mobility: An empirical investigation. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 107 (4): 693–709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, A., & McMillan, M. 2011. Offshoring jobs? Multinationals and US manufacturing employment. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93 (3): 857–875.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haskel, J. E., Pereira, S. C., & Slaughter, M. J. 2007. Does inward foreign direct investment boost the productivity of domestic firms? The Review of Economics and Statistics, 89 (3): 482–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, B. T., & Macpherson, D. A. 2003. Union membership and coverage database from the current population survey: Note. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 22 (4): 481–502.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klier, T., Ma, P., & McMillan, D. P. 2004. Comparing location decisions of domestic and foreign auto supplier plants. Working Paper No. 2004-27, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

  • Kogut, B., & Chang, S. J. 1991. Technological capabilities and Japanese foreign direct investment in the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics, 73 (3): 401–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, C., & Lawrence, R. Z. 1985. Manufacturing wage dispersion: An end game interpretation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1985 (1): 47–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, P., & Saggi, K. 2007. Multinational firms, exclusivity, and backward linkages. Journal of International Economics, 71 (1): 206–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, X., Siler, P., Wang, C., & Wei, Y. 2000. Productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment: Evidence from UK industry level panel data. Journal of International Business Studies, 31 (3): 407–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lommerud, K. E., Meland, F., & Sørgard, L. 2003. Unionised oligopoly, trade liberalisation and location choice. Economic Journal, 113 (490): 782–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lommerud, K. E., Straume, O. R., & Sørgard, L. 2005. Downstream merger with upstream market power. European Economic Review, 49 (3): 717–743.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lommerud, K. E., Straume, O. R., & Sørgard, L. 2006. National versus international mergers in unionized oligopoly. RAND Journal of Economics, 37 (1): 212–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makaev, T. 2010. The dynamics of international mergers and acquisitions. University of Maryland (mimeo).

  • Markusen, J. R., & Trofimenko, N. 2009. Teaching locals new tricks: Foreign experts as a channel of knowledge transfer. Journal of Development Economics, 88 (1): 120–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martins, P. S. 2005. Inter-Firm employee mobility, displacement, and foreign direct investment spillovers. Queen Mary: University of London (mimeo).

  • McCann, P., & Mudambi, R. 2004. The location behavior of the multinational enterprise: Some analytical issues. Growth and Change, 35 (4): 491–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCann, P., & Mudambi, R. 2005. Analytical differences in the economics of geography: The case of the multinational firm. Environment and Planning A, 37 (10): 1857–1876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mezetti, C., & Dinopoulos, E. 1991. Domestic unionization and import competition. Journal of International Economics, 31 (1–2): 79–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muendler, M.-A., & Becker, S. O. 2010. Margins of multinational labor substitution. American Economic Review, 100 (5): 1999–2030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagel, B., & Wey, C. 2013. How to counter union power? Equilibrium mergers in international oligopoly. Discussion Paper No. 89, DICE.

  • Poole, J. P. 2013. Knowledge transfers from multinational to domestic firms: Evidence from worker mobility. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 95 (2): 393–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimizu, K., Hitt, M. A., Vaidyanath, D., & Pisano, V. 2004. Theoretical foundations of cross-border mergers and acquisitions: A review of current research and recommendations for the future. Journal of International Management, 10 (3): 307–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smarzynska-Javorcik, B. 2004. Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages. American Economic Review, 94 (3): 605–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, J. Y., & Blomström, M. 1992. Foreign investment and technology transfer: A simple model. European Economic Review, 36 (1): 137–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, Y., & Liu, X. 2006. Productivity spillovers from R&D, exports and FDI in China’s manufacturing sector. Journal of International Business Studies, 37 (4): 544–557.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, Y., Liu, X., & Wang, C. 2008. Mutual productivity spillovers between foreign and local firms in China. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 32 (4): 609–631.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank ESMT-Berlin for institutional support, Claudia Baldermann for research assistance, and Sørgard thanks the Norwegian Research Council for financial support through the project “improving competition policy” on SNF. We greatly appreciate comments and suggestions by our editor (Ram Mudambi), Ragnhild Balsvik, Tomaso Duso, anonymous referees, and during presentations at the 2010 EARIE in Istanbul, University of Stavanger in March 2011, 2011 IIOC in Boston, 2012 AIB in DC, and the 2012 JIBS special issue conference on the “Multinational in Geographic Space”.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

Accepted by Ram Mudambi, Area Editor, 24 December 2013. This paper has been with the authors for four revisions.

APPENDIX

APPENDIX

Equations (1), (2) and (3) in the main text, respectively, show the inverse-linear demand, unions’ utility and firms’ profit functions. Since unions set wages in Stage 1 and firms set quantities in Stage 2, we start by solving the last stage of the game (i.e., via backwards induction). Given that one unit of labor is needed to produce one unit of output (q i =n i ), we can find the chosen amount of labor (and thus output) at Stage 2. Given the labor demand, we can derive the optimal wages chosen at Stage 1. In the absence of a cross-border M&A, the firms’ first order condition from the profit function can be used to find labor quantities. We set ∂π i /∂n i =0 for i=1.4, and solve simultaneously with respect to demand for all four firms, for example, Firm 1 – which is located in Country A – has the following labor demand:

Given the optimal value of n i (where i=1.4) at Stage 2, we can solve the union’s maximization problem by setting ∂U A /∂w A =∂U B /∂w B =0, and solving with respect to w A and w B . Then we find the domestic wage.

We compare this scenario with a situation where cross-border M&A activity takes place. In particular, we have Firm 1 merge with Firm 4; hence, the domestic-outsider is denoted with Subscript 2. As explained in the text, we allow for spillovers to all firms following a cross-border merger. While the union’s maximization problem remains the same, the merged entity faces the following maximization:

The post-merger profit functions for the domestic-outsider and foreign-outsider firms are as follows:

At Stage 2 we solve four first-order conditions simultaneously, ∂π 14 /∂n 1 =∂π 14 /∂n 4 =∂π 2 /∂n 2 =∂π 3 /∂n 3 =0, with respect to n 1 , n 2 , n 3 , and n 4 .

Given labor demand at Stage 2, the unions in Country A and B set firm wages simultaneously. Setting ∂U A /∂w 1 =∂U A /∂w 2 =∂U B /∂w 3 =∂U B /∂w 4 =0, we can solve with respect to w 1 , w 2 , w 3 , and w 4 . If we negate spillover effects (i.e., set μ i =0), we can find post-merger wages in the absence of spillovers. The wage in the domestic-insider firm is the following:

Equation (7) in the main text reports the wage in the domestic-outsider firm. It can be verified that wages in both the insider and outsider firms drop post-merger; furthermore, the post-merger wage is lower in the domestic-insider than in the domestic-outsider firm. Since our principal interest involves the domestic-outsider firm’s wage, we report the wage in Country A for Firm 2 in the presence of spillovers (μ i >0):

where

The impact of spillovers on domestic-outsider wages (which is always positive per Eq. (6)) follows:

Finally, we consider how merger relatedness affects the wage reduction following a cross-border M&A. From Eq. (9) we have the following:

This is always positive and implies that an increase in b leads to a larger post-merger wage reduction.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Clougherty, J., Gugler, K., Sørgard, L. et al. Cross-border mergers and domestic-firm wages: Integrating “spillover effects” and “bargaining effects”. J Int Bus Stud 45, 450–470 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2014.2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2014.2

Keywords

Navigation