Skip to main content
Log in

Liberal fundamentals: invisible, invasive, artful, and bloody hands

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Relations and Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Returning to liberalism's Scottish Enlightenment precursors suggests that the liberal order might best be described by the tension between its assertions about the smoothing natural harmonies within the social order and its doubts about whether those harmonies can appear spontaneously and therefore require aggressive projects of reform and correction. Although committed to the inevitability and inexorability of progress, such doubts led Scottish Enlightenment figures to strategies that even today continue to mark liberalism's effort to purify modern progress of tragedy's taint. We continue to justify apparent social failings as necessary to the natural order, regarding them instead as advantages in a Providentialist manner (Smith and Hume). We preserve our faith in commercial society by aggressively reforming and correcting those inside and outside others who resist the inevitabilities we have embraced (Millar). We accept the disorders and instabilities inherent in modern market society, but replace our hope in the automaticity of adjustment with a belief in the capacity of the state or some form of international governance to resolve tensions in some higher-order liberalism (Steuart). We call for a moral revival to restore values that our contemporary liberal institutions cannot possibly sustain (Ferguson). In sum, maintaining liberalism's idealised vision of itself in the face of these necessary limits and ill consequences calls forth the purificatory zeal of the fundamentalist. If we wish to move past a response that offers us more liberalism and more zeal as a solution to the problems of liberalism, we need something that is both within and beyond liberal fundamentals: a liberalism that accepts truths beyond itself; that looks to multiple ontologies for political and ethical resources; and that accepts plural and multiple versions of virtue and progress negotiated between liberalism's fundamentals and varying local ideals and conditions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Kordela (2007: 17) uses Lacan's term ‘real’ to point to the impossible but necessary gestures constitutive of the modern symbolic order — gestures that must be hidden as part of suturing the cracks or wounds in that order. Similarly, Edkins (1999: 113) uses the ‘real’ to indicate an ‘antagonism’ that ‘prevents closure of the social field, a totalization that is always already impossible’.

  2. As we were at the ABRI-ISA Conference, Rio de Janiero, Brazil, 22–24 July, 2009.

References

  • Barkawi, Tarak and Mark Laffey, eds (2001) Democracy, Liberalism, and War: Rethinking the Democratic Peace Debate, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benton, Ted (1990) ‘Adam Ferguson and the Enterprise Culture’, in Peter Hulme and Ludmilla Jordanova, eds, The Enlightenment and Its Shadows, 101–20, London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, Christopher (1997) Social Theory of the Scottish Enlightenment, Edinburgh: University of Edinburgh.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaney, David L. and Naeem Inayatullah (2010) Savage Economics: Wealth, Poverty, and the Temporal Walls of Capitalism, London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, Richard (2008) ‘Manners and Morals: David Hume on Civility, Commerce, and the Social Construction of Difference’, in Carl Wennerlind and Margaret Schabas, eds, David Hume's Political Economy, 68–85, London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Broadie, Alexander (2001) The Scottish Enlightenment: The Historical Age of the Historical Nation, Edinburgh: Edinburgh University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, Wendy (2001) Politics Out of History, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchan, Bruce (2006) ‘Civilisation, Sovereignty and War: The Scottish Enlightenment and International Relations’, International Relations 20 (2): 177–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burchell, Graham (1991) ‘Peculiar Interests: Civil Society and Governing “The System of Natural Liberty”’, in Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon and Peter Miller, eds, The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality, 119–49, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Burrow, J.W. (1988) Whigs and Liberals: Continuity and Change in English Political Thought, Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, James (1998) England in 1819: The Politics of Literary Culture and the Case of Romantic Historicism, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crane, George T. and Abla Amawi, eds (1997) The Theoretical Structure of International Political Economy: A Reader, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davie, G.E. (1967) ‘Anglophobe and Anglophile’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy XIV (3): 291–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deudney, Daniel (2007) Bounding Power, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickey, Laurence (1987) Hegel: Religion, Economics, and the Politics of Spirit, 1770–1807, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Doujon, Ruhdan (1994) ‘Steuart's Position on Economic Progress’, The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 1 (3): 495–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duke, Michael I. (1979) ‘David Hume and Monetary Adjustment’, History of Political Economy 11 (4): 572–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edkins, Jenny (1999) Poststructuralism and International Relations: Bringing the Political Back In, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, Adam (1995) An Essay on the History of Civil Society, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frieden, Jeffrey A. and David A. Lake, eds (1995) International Political Economy: Perspectives on Global Power and Wealth, 3rd edn., New York: St. Martin's Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froebel, Folker, Jurgen Heinrich and Otto Kreye (1980) The New International Division of Labor, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilpin, Robert (1987) The Political Economy of International Relations, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch, Nils Petter (2008) ‘The Liberal Moment Fifteen Years On’, International Studies Quarterly 52 (4): 691–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griswold Jr., Charles L. (1999) Adam Smith and the Virtues of Enlightenment, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haakonssen, Knud (2005) Natural Law and Moral Philosophy: From Grotius to the Scottish Enlightenment, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helleiner, Eric (2002) ‘Economic Nationalism as a Challenge to Economic Liberalism? Lessons from the 19th Century’, International Studies Quarterly 46 (3): 307–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, Lisa (1997) ‘Adam Ferguson and the Paradox of Progress and Decline’, History of Political Thought XVIII (4): 677–706.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, Albert O. (1977) The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before its Triumph, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hont, Istvan (1983) ‘The “Rich Country-Poor Country” Debate in Scottish Political Economy’, in Michael Ignatieff, ed., Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment, 271–315, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hume, David (1985) Essays: Moral, Political and Literary in Eugene F. Miller, ed., Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inayatullah, Naeem and David L. Blaney (2004) International Relations and the Problem of Difference, New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Isaak, Robert A. (2000) Managing World Economic Change: International Political Economy, Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jahn, Beate (2005) ‘Kant, Mill, and Illiberal Legacies in International Affairs’, International Organization 59 (1): 177–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kettler, David (1965) The Social and Political Thought of Adam Ferguson, Columbus, OH: Ohio State University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kordela, Kiarina (2007) $urplus: Spinoza, Lacan, Albany, NY: SUNY.

    Google Scholar 

  • Latham, Robert (1997) The Liberal Moment: Modernity, Security, and the Making of Postwar International Order, New York: Columbia University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manzer, Robert A. (1996) ‘The Promise of Peace? Hume and Smith on the Effects of Commerce on War and Peace’, Hume Studies XXII (2): 369–382.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meek, Ronald L. (1965) The Rise and Fall of the Concept of the Economic Machine, Leicester: Leicester University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meek, Ronald L. (1967) Economics and Ideology and Other Essays: Studies in the Development of Economic Thought, London: Chapman and Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meek, Ronald L. (1976) Social Science and the Ignoble Savage, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merikoski, Ingrid A. (2002) ‘The Challenge of Material Progress: The Scottish Enlightenment and Christian Stoicism’, The Journal of the Historical Society II (1): 55–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millar, John (1979a) ‘The Advancement of Manufactures, Commerce, and the Arts’, in William C. Lehman, ed., John Millar of Glasgow, 1735–1801: His Life and Thought and His Contribution to Sociological Analysis, 326–39, New York: Arno.

    Google Scholar 

  • Millar, John (1979b) ‘The Origins of the Distinction of Ranks’, in William C. Lehman, ed., John Millar of Glasgow, 1735–1801: His Life and Thought and His Contribution to Sociological Analysis, 175–322, New York: Arno.

    Google Scholar 

  • Millar, John (1997) A Historical View of the English Government Volume IV, Bristol: Thoemmes Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, Timothy (2000) ‘The Stage of Modernity’, in Timothy Mitchell, ed., Questions of Modernity, 1–39, Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montag, Warren (2006) ‘Necro-Economics: Adam Smith and Death in the Life of the Universal’, Radical Philosophy 134: 7–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nandy, Ashis (1987) Traditions, Tyranny, and Utopias: Essays on the Politics of Awareness, Delhi: Oxford University.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, Robert and Marc Williams (2004) Global Political Economy: Evolution and Dynamics, London: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Onuf, Nicholas G. and Peter Onuf (2006) Nations, Markets, and War: Modern History and the American Civil War, Charlotte, NC: University of Virginia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pocock, J.G.A. (1975) The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, Karl (2001) The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time, Boston, MA: Beacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poovey, Mary (1998) A History of the Modern Fact: Problems of Knowledge in the Science of Wealth and Society, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, Justin (1994) Empire of Civil Society: A Critique of the Realist Theory of International Relations, London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sahlins, Marshall (1972) Stone Age Economics, New York: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, S.R. (1957) The Economics of Sir James Steuart, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, Andrew (1965) ‘Economics and History — The Scottish Enlightenment’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy 12 (1): 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, Quentin (1998) Liberty Before Liberalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Adam (1976a) The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Adam (1976b) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Adam (1982) Lectures on Jurisprudence, Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Paul B. (1996) ‘Conjecture, Acquiescence, and John Millar's History of Ireland’, The European Legacy 1 (8): 2227–2248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steuart, James (1966) An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Oeconomy: Being an Essay on the Science of Domestic Policy in Free Nations, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teichgraeber, Richard F. (1986) ‘Free Trade’ and Moral Philosophy: Rethinking the Sources of Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations, Durham, NC: Duke University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Todorov, Tzvetan (2005) The New World Disorder: Reflections of a European, Cambridge: Polity.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trouillot, Michel-Rolph (1991) ‘Anthropology and the Savage Slot’, in Richard G. Fox, ed., Recapturing Anthropology: Working in the Present, 17–44, Santa Fe, NM: School of American Research Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Urquhart, Robert (1996) ‘The Trade Wind, the Statesman and the System of Commerce: Sir James Steuart's Vision of Political Economy’, The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 3 (3): 379–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vernon, Raymond (1966) ‘International Investment and International Trade in the Product Life Cycle’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 80 (2): 190–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winch, Donald (1996) Riches and Poverty: An Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1750–1834, Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wyatt-Walter, Andrew (1996) ‘Adam Smith and the Liberal Tradition in International Relations’, Review of International Studies 22 (1): 5–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Thanks to Beate Jahn, Rose Shinko, Ron Krebs, Patrick Jackson, Taylor Long, participants in the Minnesota International Relations Colloquium, especially Joan Tronto, and two anonymous reviewers for their comments and Amanda Peterson and Emma Van Emmerik for editorial assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Inayatullah, N., Blaney, D. Liberal fundamentals: invisible, invasive, artful, and bloody hands. J Int Relat Dev 15, 290–315 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1057/jird.2011.33

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/jird.2011.33

Keywords

Navigation