Skip to main content
Log in

Farrell revisited–Visualizing properties of DEA production frontiers

  • Special Issue Paper
  • Published:
Journal of the Operational Research Society

Abstract

The contributions of the paper are threefold: (i) compare with mathematical rigour the data envelopment analysis (DEA) model of Charnes, Cooper, and Rhodes and the Farrell model exhibiting constant returns to scale, (ii) reinterpret the contribution of Farrell and Fieldhouse that extended the analysis to variables returns to scale and establish the connection with the approach in Banker, Charnes, and Cooper, and (iii) provide graphical visualization of properties of the frontier function. Both papers by Farrell emphasized the importance of graphical visualization of non-parametric frontier functions, but, to our knowledge, this is seldom followed up in the literature. We use a graphical package (EffiVision) with a numerical representation of the frontier functions, representing the contemporary development of visualization. By making suitable cuts through the DEA frontier in multidimensional space, various graphical representations of features of economic interest can be done. Development of ray average cost function and scale elasticity plots are novel illustrations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6

References

  • Banker RD, Charnes A and Cooper WW (1984). Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies . Mngt Sci 39: 1078–1092.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boles JN (1967). Efficiency squared—efficient computation of efficiency indexes . In: Western Farm Economic Association, Proceedings 1966, pp. 137–142.

  • Boles JN (1971). The 1130 Farrell efficiency system–multiple products, multiple factors. Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics, University of California: Berkeley, USA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charnes A, Cooper WW and Rhodes E (1978). Measuring the efficiency of decision making units . Eur J Opl Res 2: 429–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper WW, Seiford LM and Tone K (2000). Data Envelopment Analysis: A Comprehensive Text with Models, Applications, References and DEA-Solver Software . Kluwer Academic Publishers: Dordrecht/Boston/London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dantzig GB (1998). Linear Programming and Extensions . Princeton Landmarks in Mathematics. Princeton University Press: Princeton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell MJ (1957). The measurement of productive efficiency . J R Stat Soc Ser A-G 120(III): 253–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell MJ and Fieldhouse M (1962). Estimating efficient production functions under increasing returns to scale . J R Stat Soc Ser A-G 125: 252–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frisch R (1965). Theory of Production . D. Reidel: Dordrecht.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund FR and Hjalmarsson L (2004). Are all scales optimal in DEA? Theory and empirical evidence . J Prod Anal 21(1): 25–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund FR and Sarafoglou N (2002). On the origins of data envelopment analysis . J Prod Anal 17: 23–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund FR and Sarafoglou N (2005). The tale of two research communities: the diffusion of research on productive efficiency . Int J Prod Econ 98(1): 17–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund FR, Hjalmarsson L, Krivonozhko VE and Utkin OB (2007). Calculation of scale elasticities in DEA models: Direct and indirect approaches . J Prod Anal 28(1–2): 45–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman AJ (1957). Discussion on Mr. Farrell's paper. In: The measurement of productive efficiency . J R Stat Soc Ser A-G 120(III): 284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krivonozhko V, Utkin OB, Volodin AV, Sablin IA and Patrin M (2004). Constructions of economic functions and calculation of marginal rates in DEA using parametric optimization methods . J Opl Res Soc 55: 1049–1058.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krivonozhko V, Utkin OB, Volodin AV and Sablin IA (2005). About the structure of boundary points in DEA . J Opl Res Soc 56: 1373–1378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meller P (1976). Efficiency frontiers for industrial establishments of different sizes . Explorations Econ Res, Occasional Papers of the National Bureau of Economic Research 3: 379–407.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nikaido H (1968). Convex Structures and Economic Theory . Academic Press: New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seitz WD (1970). The measurement of efficiency relative to a frontier production function . Am J Agric Econ 52: 505–511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seitz WD (1971). Productive efficiency in the steam-electric generating industry . J Polit Econ 79: 878–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shephard RW (1970). Theory of Cost and Production Functions, first edition, 1953. Princeton University Press: New Jersey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Todd D (1977). Efficiency and size: Comments and extensions . Econ Soc Rev 8: 305–312.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

A first draft was written while Professor Vladimir Krivonozhko visited the Frisch Centre for four weeks in January and February 2007 on a grant from the Frisch Centre. Helpful comments from two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to F R Førsund.

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 1

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 1

Suppose that we obtain an optimal solution of problem (1). Let J B be the index set of optimal basic variables, and let λ j *,jJ B, be the optimal variables. Optimization theory (Dantzig, 1998) ensures that in this optimal solution vector not more than m of the λ j * will be strictly positive and the rest will be zero.

Let us consider the hyperplane H going through vectors P j ,jJ B, which form the optimal basis. Such basis always exists and contains precisely m vectors. Farrell introduced artificial points in problem (1) to ensure the existence of feasible bases. Observe that hyperplane H does not contain the origin, since otherwise vectors P j , jJ B, would be linearly dependent. Then, point P k can be represented in the form

Introducing λ j ′=λ j */η 1, the expression after the second equality sign is obtained, and introducing the vector P k ′ yields the expression after the third equality sign.

From (1) and (A.1), it follows that

So, we associate the value function (1) with the distance along line OP k ′ from point P k to point P k ′ that belongs to the convex combination of vectors P j , jJ B.

It can be shown that

  1. a)

    if η 1<1, then point P k and the origin are on the same side of hyperplane H,

  2. b)

    if η 1>1, then hyperplane H separates the origin and the point P k ,

  3. c)

    if η 1=1, then points P k ′ and P k coincide.

Hence, the value function of problem (1) reaches at least the value η 1. The case η 1<1 is not possible, because the feasible solution λ k =1, λ j =0, jk, increases the value function I 1=1, contradicting the optimality of solution λ j *, jJ B, I 1 *=η 1 of problem (1).

Observe that the finite optimal solution of problem (1) exists as there is a finite set of feasible bases of problem (1).

Now, turning to problem (3), it follows from (A.1) and (A.2) that variables λ j =λ j ′ if jJ B, λ j =0 if jJ B, and θ=1/η 1 form a feasible solution of problem (3). Hence, the following relations hold:

Conversely, consider optimization problem (3). From the first part of the proof it follows that problem (3) has a feasible solution. So, according to convex analysis (Nikaido, 1968), there exists a unique point P k ′ on the segment OP k , which belongs to some facet of the polyhedron (3), this point is represented in the form

where P j , jJ 1, are vertices of the feasible set (3) which determines this facet. Because point P k ′ is unique on the segment OP k , problem (3) has an optimal solution λ j =λ j ′ if jJ 1, λ j =0 otherwise, I 2=θ. (Note that, though the point P k ′ is unique, solution vectors in the variables λ j *, jJ B, may not be unique, they may constitute a whole set of optimal solutions.)

The case θ=1 takes place when points P k and P k ′ coincide. From (A.1) and (A.4), it follows that variables λ j =(1/θ)λ j ′ if jJ 1, λ j =0 if jJ 1, form a feasible solution of problem (1). Hence, for the optimal value function of problem (1) the following relations hold:

Thus, two opposite inequalities (A.3) and (A.5) establish that I 2=1/I 1. Relations (4) follow immediately from (A.1) and (A.4). This completes the proof. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Førsund, F., Kittelsen, S. & Krivonozhko, V. Farrell revisited–Visualizing properties of DEA production frontiers. J Oper Res Soc 60, 1535–1545 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1057/jors.2008.185

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/jors.2008.185

Keywords

Navigation