Skip to main content
Log in

Pricing strategy in the presence of reference prices with thresholds

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Aims and scope

Abstract

Reference price models allow for the explicit incorporation of inter-temporal effects of pricing decisions. We introduce a reference price model with thresholds within which there are no reference effects. For frequently purchased items such as groceries, a pricing action in this period may affect demand in this period and in the next period, and reference price models build that effect into an expected price. Previous reference models have been structurally limited to either single-price or cyclical price strategies but not both. The incorporation of thresholds allows for both types of pricing strategies, depending on the specific parameters for the model. We investigate the conditions under which a price cycles and those under which a single price is optimal. We also present propositions for the reduction of the search space to improve computational performance and present results of computational experiments to highlight key results. Understanding the nature of the product demand can help managers develop pricing strategies that maximize their profits.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alford, B.L. and Biswas, A. (2002) The effects of discount level, price consciousness and sale proneness on consumers’ price perception and behavioral intention. Journal of Business Research 55 (9): 775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, B.A. and Casielles, R.V. (2006) How could reference price and loyalty influence brand choice? International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation Management 6 (3/4): 287.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C.K., Rasmussen, H. and MacDonald, L. (2005) Competitive pricing with dynamic asymmetric price effects. International Transactions in Operational Research 12 (5): 509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner, B. and Steiner, W.J. (2007) Are consumers heterogeneous in their preferences for odd and even prices? Findings from a choice-based conjoint study. International Journal of Research in Marketing 24 (4): 312–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berkowitz, E.N. and Walton, J.R. (1980) Contextual influences on consumer price responses: An experimental analysis. Journal of Marketing Research 17 (3): 349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biswas, A. and Blair, E.A. (1991) Contextual effects of reference prices in retail advertisements. Journal of Marketing 55 (3): 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biswas, A. and Sherrell, D.L. (1993) The influence of product knowledge and brand name on internal price standards and confidence. Psychology and Marketing 10 (1): 31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biswas, A., Pullig, C., Krishnan, B.C. and Burton, S. (1999) Consumer evaluation of reference price advertisements: Effects of other brands’ prices and semantic cues. Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 18 (1): 52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blattberg, R.C., Briesch, R. and Fox, E.J. (1995) How promotions work. Marketing Science (1986–1998) 14 (3): 122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bray, J.P. and Harris, C. (2006) The effect of 9-ending prices on retail sales: A quantitative UK based field study. Journal of Marketing Management 22 (5/6): 601–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briesch, R.A., Krishnamurthi, L., Mazumdar, T. and Raj, S.P. (1997) A comparative analysis of reference price models. Journal of Consumer Research 24 (2): 202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campo, S. and Yague, M.J. (2007a) Effects of price promotions on the perceived price. International Journal of Service Industry Management 18 (3-4): 269–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campo, S. and Yague, M.J. (2007b) The perception of price discounts according to consumer's characteristics. Journal of Revenue Pricing Management 6 (2): 86–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandrashekaran, R. and Grewal, D. (2006) Anchoring effects of advertised reference price and sale price: The moderating role of saving presentation format. Journal of Business Research 59 (10/11): 1063.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, S., Monroe, K.B. and Lou, Y. (1998) The effects of framing price promotion messages on consumers’ perceptions and purchase intentions. Journal of Retailing 74 (3): 353–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DelVecchio, D. and Craig, A.W. (2008) Mode matters: An exemplar-prototype hybrid (EPH) model of reference price formation. Journal of Product and Brand Management 17 (4): 272–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DelVecchio, D., Krishnan, H.S. and Smith, D.C. (2007) Cents or percent? The effects of promotion framing on price expectations and choice. Journal of Marketing 71 (3): 158–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, W.D. and Campbell, L. (1989) The framing of sales promotions: Effects on reference price change. Advances in Consumer Research 16 (1): 241–247.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fibich, G., Gavious, A. and Lowengart, O. (2003) Explicit solutions of optimization models and differential games with nonsmooth (asymmetric) reference price effects. Operations Research 51 (5): 721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fibich, G., Gavious, A. and Lowengart, O. (2007) Optimal price promotion in the presence of asymmetric reference-price effects. Managerial and Decision Economics 28 (6): 569–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaur, V. and Fisher, M.L. (2005) In-store experiments to determine the impact of price on sales. Production and Operations Management 14 (4): 377–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gimpl-Heersink, L., Rudlof, C., Fleischmann, M. and Taudes, A. (2008) Integrating pricing and inventory control: Is it worth the effort? Business Research 1 (1): 106–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenleaf, E.A. (1995) The impact of reference price effects on the profitability of price promotions. Marketing Science 14 (1): 82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, S. and Cooper, L.G. (1992) The discounting of discounts and promotion thresholds. Journal of Consumer Research 19 (3): 401–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu, H., Parsa, H.G. and Khan, M. (2006) Effectiveness of price discount levels and formats in service industries. Journal of Services Research 6 (Special Issue): 67–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hu, W. (2007) Bargains or rip-offs? Reference price effects in conjoint stated demand. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 32 (2): 256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janiszewski, C. and Cunha Jr, M.C. (2004) The influence of price discount framing on the evaluation of a product bundle. Journal of Consumer Research 30 (4): 534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janiszewski, C. and Lichtenstein, D.R. (1999) A range theory account of price perception. Journal of Consumer Research 25 (4): 353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jianping, L. and Kanetkar, V. (2006) Price endings: Magic and math. Journal of Product Brand Management 15 (6): 377–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalwani, M.U. and Yim, C.K. (1992) Consumer price and promotion expectations: An experimental study. Journal of Marketing Research 29 (1): 90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalyanaram, G. and Little, J.D.C. (1994) An empirical analysis of latitude of price acceptance in consumer package goods. Journal of Consumer Research 21 (3): 408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalyanaram, G. and Winer, R.S. (1995) Empirical generalizations from reference price research. Marketing Science 14 (3): 161–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khouja, M., Robbins, S.S. and Rajagopalan, H.K. (2008) Optimal pricing and delayed incentives in a heterogeneous consumer market. Journal of Revenue Pricing Management 7 (1): 85–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopalle, P. et al (2009) Retailer pricing and competitive effects. Journal of Retailing 85 (1): 56–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopalle, P.K., Rao, A.G. and Assuncao, J.L. (1996) Asymmetric reference price effects and dynamic pricing policies. Marketing Science 15 (1): 60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krider, R.E. and Han, S.M. (2004) Promotion thresholds: Price change insensitivity or risk hurdle? Canadian Journal of Administrative Sciences 21 (3): 255–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lattin, J.M. and Bucklin, R.E. (1989) Reference effects of price and promotion on brand choice be. Journal of Marketing Research 26 (3): 299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, M. (2004) The influence of loyalty programs and short-term promotions on customer retention. Journal of Marketing Research 41 (3): 281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenstein, D.R., Bloch, P.H. and Black, W.C. (1988) Correlates of price acceptability. Journal of Consumer Research 15 (2): 243–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowengart, O., Mizrahi, S. and Yosef, R. (2003) Effect of consumer characteristics on optimal reference price. Journal of Revenue Pricing Management 2 (3): 201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathies, C. and Gudergan, S. (2007) Revenue management and customer centric marketing – How do they influence travellers’ choices? Journal of Revenue Pricing Management 6 (4): 331–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, G.E. and Winer, R.S. (1992) An empirical analysis of internal and external reference prices using scanner data. Journal of Consumer Research 19 (1): 62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazumdar, T., Raj, S.P. and Sinha, I. (2005) Reference price research: Review and propositions. Journal of Marketing 69 (4): 84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McClure, J. and Kumcu, E. (2008) Promotions and product pricing: Parsimony versus veblenesque demand. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 65 (1): 105–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miao-Shen, C. and Chuan-Biau, C. (1999) The optimal penetration pricing strategy model under the dynamic demand function. Asia-Pacific Journal of Operational Research 16 (2): 139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moon, S. and Voss, G. (2009) How do price range shoppers differ from reference price point shoppers? Journal of Business Research 62 (1): 31–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munnukka, J. (2006) Pricing method as a tool for improved price perception. Journal of Revenue Pricing Management 5 (3): 207–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Natter, M., Reutterer, T., Mild, A. and Taudes, A. (2007) An assortmentwide decision-support system for dynamic pricing and promotion planning in DIY retailing. Marketing Science 26 (4): 576–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nerlove, M. (1958) Adaptive expectations and cobweb phenomena. Quarterly Journal of Economics 72 (2): 227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen, A., Heeler, R.A. and Taran, Z. (2007) High-low context cultures and price-ending practices. Journal of Product Brand Management 16 (3): 206–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niedrich, R.W., Sharma, S. and Wedell, D.H. (2001) Reference price and price perceptions: A comparison of alternative models. Journal of Consumer Research 28 (3): 339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pauwels, K., Srinivasan, S. and Franses, P.H. (2007) When do price thresholds matter in retail categories? Marketing Science 26 (1): 83–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popescu, I. and Wu, Y. (2007) Dynamic pricing strategies with reference effects. Operations Research 55 (3): 413–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psaraftis, H. (1983) An exact algorithm for the single vehicle many-to-many dial-a-ride problem with time windows. Transportation Science 17 (3): 351–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schindler, R.M. (2009) Patterns of price endings used in US and Japanese price advertising. International Marketing Review 26 (1): 17–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shirai, M. (2003) An analysis of multi-dimensional internal reference prices. Advances in Consumer Research 30 (1): 258–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shirai, M. (2004) Consumer evaluation of multiple internal reference prices. Advances in Consumer Research 31 (1): 580–583.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tellis, G.J. (1988a) Advertising exposure, loyalty, and brand purchase: A two-staged model of choice. Journal of Marketing Research 25 (2): 134–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tellis, G.J. (1988b) The price elasticity of selective demand: A meta-analysis of economic models of sales. Journal of Marketing Research 25 (4): 331–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, M. and Menon, G. (2007) When internal reference prices and price expectations diverge: The role of confidence. Journal of Marketing Research 44 (3): 401–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turui, N. and Dahana, W. (2006) Estimating heterogeneous price thresholds. Marketing Science 25 (4): 384–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Urban, T.L. (2008) Coordinating pricing and inventory decisions under reference price effects. International Journal of Manufacturing Technology and Management 13 (1): 78–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winer, R.S. (1986) A reference price model of brand choice for frequently purchased products. Journal of Consumer Research 13 (2): 250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

APPENDIX

APPENDIX

Proofs of propositions

Proof of Proposition 1 It is clear that:

This can be expanded to:

Proof of Proposition 2 This proof is based on the definition of a reference price (equation (1)). We use pc(i)−1 and rc(i)−1, i=1, …, M to denote the price and reference price in the period that immediately precedes the period where pc(i) and rc(i) occurred, respectively. By definition of the reference price we have αrc(1)−1=rc(1)−(1−α)pc(1)−1, and by the ordering we have αrc(1)<αrc(1)−1. It follows that αrc(1)<rc(1)−(1−α)pc(1)−1, or pc(1)−1<rc(1). This establishes part (1). Similar arguments can be used to show part (2). Part (3) follows immediately from parts (1) and (2). For part (4), rc(1)pc(1) has to hold, otherwise the resulting reference price in the subsequent period would be smaller than rc(1), contradicting the fact that rc(1)=min1⩽mM r cm . A similar argument can be used to show that rc(M)pc(M).

Thus the period corresponding to rc(1) and rc(M) corresponds to a loss and gain, respectively.

Proof of Proposition 3 This follows easily from the fact that the reference price in period t is a convex combination of the reference price and price in period t−1, and that r t p t and r t p t for a loss and gain period, respectively.

Knowing that it suffices to establish that to show that

Proof of Lemma 1 We first assume that we have a one-period cycle and show, by contradiction, that only p* will maximize the profit. Assume that price charged p. We consider two cases.

Case 1: < p*.

As price is constant, we have . We know by definition that < g(p*). There is a finite loss in profit, owing to increasing price, from to p* that is equal to (p*c)β L (p*). On the other hand, there is a long-term loss in profit as p*=arg max p g(p). Clearly, that is the short-term loss in profit by moving to p* is less than the long-term loss in profit by staying at Thus a single-price strategy will never stabilize below p*.

Case 2: When > p*.

In this case, decreasing the price to p* generates a gain equal to (p*c)β G (p*)>0, and as g(p*)>

we conclude that a single-price strategy will never stabilize above p*.

Proof of Theorem 1 We must show that for any M-period cycle, M>1, the profit (equation (5)) is not superior to that obtained for a one-period cycle charging p*. We do not consider the initial adjustment that might be required to achieve the steady-state cycle. We consider the long-term steady-state pricing policy and the associated cycle of repeating prices. Let the vectors (pc1, pc2, …, p cM ) and (rc1, rc2, …, r cM ) denote the prices and reference prices in an M-period cycle. Note that p cM , the last price in the cycle, will be followed by pc1, the first price in the next cycle. We also define x+=max(x, 0) and x=min(x, 0). Our goal is to show that for M>1.

We now consider an arbitrary cycle of length M, with K consecutive gains followed by J consecutive losses. We define all gains, (r cm p cm )+, G k , and losses (r cm p cm ), L j .

We know from Proposition 3 that the losses will occur in sequence with ascending reference price, where , and similarly that the gains will occur in order of descending reference price and specify them such that We know from Proposition 1 that

We now consider L1 (the loss with the lowest reference price) and G K (the gain with the lowest reference price). As L1 is a loss, we know that and using a similar logic that We assume, without loss of generality, that c=0. We recall that β L β G .

For an M=2 cycle, we know that ∣L1∣=G1 and can easily see that as and β L >β G . There is, therefore, no case where M=2 is optimal. It is easy to apply that same logic to M>2.

Step 1: If ∣L1∣=G K , we know from above that the lost profit from L1 exceeds the profit gained from G K . And now consider L2 and GK−1. It is worth noting that as ∣L1∣=G K , and , we get . Then

This means that . We can now start this process again by comparing L2 and GK−1. We also see that and therefore we have the same starting condition as we did where the first loss under consideration has a lower reference price than the first gain under consideration.

Step 2: If ∣L1∣>G K , we consider S additional gains such that but . If we partition GKS into GKS′ and GKS″ such that . We know that because they are gains, i=KS … K, and it follows that . Now

and so

which means that i=KSK, which gives us so the profit lost due to the loss is greater than the profit gained owing to the matching gains. If we do not partition GKS, the component disappears but the profit impacts are the same. The next step is to compare L2 and GKS or GK−(s+1). We note before proceeding that as

but

it is easily shown that and therefore we have the same beginning condition where the first loss under consideration has a lower reference price than the first gain under consideration.

Step 3: If ∣L1∣<G K , we consider S additional losses such that but . If we partition L S into L S ′ and L S ″ such that . We know that as they are losses, i=1 … S. We also know that because of the definition of reference price. It follows then that . If we do not partition L S , the L S ″/L S component disappears but the profit impacts are the same. Once again, the next step is to compare GK−1 and L S ′ or Ls+1. We can consider the finishing condition with respect to reference prices.

but

and show that has the same beginning condition where the first loss under consideration has a lower reference price than the first gain under consideration.

This iterative process where step 1, 2 or 3 is applied sequentially as appropriate to the entire M-period cycle results in definitive proof that there is no cycle M>1 that provides more profit than the single price.

In the case where the K gains and/or J losses are not consecutive, we approach the problem similarly by considering the sub-cycles of the large price cycle within which one or more gains precede one or more losses. The steps (1 through 3) outlined above are applied to the sub-cycles, beginning with the highest reference price that is formed by a gain but involves a loss (an inflection point). We can show that each sub-cycle, and subsequently the entire cycle, results in a net loss of profit.

There is, therefore, no cycle M>1, which is superior to M=1, when β L β G .

Proof of Lemma 2 We know from Lemma 1 that if a single price is optimal, the price is p* in the absence of thresholds. The same is true with thresholds. Recall that we considered a price policy with a single price, , that is not equal to p*.

Case 1: When <p*, we have , as price is constant. There is a finite loss in profit (⩾ 0) owing to moving to p* that is (p*c)β L ( +ρp*). There could be no loss in profit owing to moving to p* because the price increases can happen in increments such that the loss threshold is never exceeded, but it may also be worthwhile to incur the loss about ρ in the short term to increase the profits in the long term. We know g( ) < g(p*). Profit will always increase by moving the price up to p*. Thus a single-price strategy will never stabilize below p* even within the presence of thresholds.

Case 2: When >p*, the proof is straightforward. We know that g()<g(p*) and (p*c)β G ( τp*)+⩾0. Thus we gain by moving to p* as we will either have a positive reference gain effect or no reference effect and the price effect is positive.

Proof of Theorem 2 Consider an M=2 cycle in which we subtract a small increment, δ, from p* for one price and add the increment to p* for the second price. We choose a value such that δ⩽0.5ρ. We specify: pc1=p*+δ and pc2=p*δ. Reference prices are: rc2=αrc1+(1−α)pc1 and rc1=αrc2+(1−α)pc2. Then:

Similarly

We now define Y, the loss effect, such that

for 0⩽α⩽1, ((1+α2−2α)/(1−α2))⩽1 then

It is clear, therefore, that Y=0. For the single-price strategy to be optimal:

But Y=0, thus

Now we divide both sides by δ and take the limits as δ → 0 and as g is continuous and differentiable

which is impossible as the right-hand side is always positive. Thus, with a loss threshold only, the price always cycles.

Proof of Theorem 3 We begin with the same arbitrary M-period cycle we specified in the proof for Theorem 1. We have cycle profit:

where

We showed in the proof of Theorem 1 that:

for all cycle lengths. We know τ>0, and therefore

and

Thus in no case where there is a gain threshold only would a cyclical price be optimal.

Proof of Lemma 3 Consider an optimal solution in which the range [pmin, pmax] does not include p*. If pmax<p*, each price in the M-period price cycle can be increased by p*pmax. In the steady-state case, this would increase each of the reference prices in the M-period cycle by the same amount. The gaps between price and reference price in each period will be unchanged, and therefore there would be no change in the reference component of the profit function, as the reference gaps for price decreases and price increases would not change. Owing to the concavity of g(p) we know that the non-reference component of each period's profit will increase as prices move closer to p*.

In the case where pmin>p*, we similarly subtract pminp* from each price in the M-period price cycle. In all cases, the solution is improved if the range includes p*.

Proof of Lemma 4 We note that for M>1:

We will use the absolute threshold example for illustration, but the proportional threshold example is analogous. If this were not true, then M=1 and a single-price strategy is optimal.

First, for simplification let us specify the individual elements of the equation above.

Now, consider a portion of an optimal price cycle of length M with a sequence p ci >p cj >p ck , where 0<i<j<kM and i, j, k are integer. This sequence has two consecutive price decreases where we assume that r cj p cj < τ, and the threshold is not exceeded in that interval. If we eliminate p cj we have a cycle of length M−1. Component B will decrease by g(p*)−g(p cj ). If p cj =p*, component B will not change. Component C may or may not change. We know that, at worst, this will stay the same if there is no threshold effect. Note the reference price after charging p ck in the original sequence is r ck =α2r cj +(αα2)p cj +(1−α)p ck . If we skip the interim price p cj , the new reference price is αr cj +(1−α)p ck , which then would lead to the potential for decrease in component C. Now we consider component A. The step of eliminating the intermediate price would not change if r cj τp ck ⩽0, but would increase if r cj τp ck >0. By eliminating the interim price, in which the reference threshold was not exceeded, we have increased profit.

Proof of Lemma 5 The proof builds on that for Lemma 3. We relax the assumption that r cj p cj < τ, so that the threshold may be exceeded in the interim step. Otherwise, our specification of p ci > p cj > p ck remains the same. The impacts on components B and C are identical. We now consider the impact on Component A. With the interim step, the reference gains are (r cj τp cj )+(r ck τp ck ) if (r cj τp cj ) > 0, and (r ck τp ck ) > 0. Both are, by definition, no lower than zero.

Lemma 3 establishes that we will not consider price paths in which either of the components are less than zero. Without the interim step, the reference gains are r cj τp ck . The difference between the two is the gain effect lost by eliminating the interim step. We find the difference in the reference gaps between the two scenarios (with and without interim step p cj ): (r cj τp cj )+(r ck τp ck )−(r cj τp ck ) that then can be simplified:

It is worth noting that α(r cj p cj )−τ may be negative, depending on the size of τ. The difference in reference gap may be smaller than having to overcome one more gain threshold. Removing the interim step, p ck , reduces component B by (g(p*)−g(p cj )). The amount lost would be from component A and is at least (p cj p ck )β G (r cj τp cj )+(p ck c)β G (α(r cj p cj )−τ), where the second term may, in fact, be negative. If

for any p ck < p cj , then there will be no price decrease from p cj to p ck .

Proof of Lemma 6 Consider an optimal price path in which a price increase to price p cj falls below the minimum of r cj +ρ and p* in the price path p i <p j <p k . We assume in the first case that p ck is greater than the minimum of r cj +ρ and p*. Now, if we increase p cj to the minimum of r cj +ρ and p*, we need to evaluate the impact on each of the components A, B and C. M will not change, as we are not inserting or removing a price but rather just increasing p cj .

  • Component A will increase. A higher reference price, r cj , will result because p cj is higher. Subsequent reference prices will also be higher. We know that r ct τp ct >0 at least once or M=1 and a constant price would be optimal.

  • Component B will decrease. An increase in p cj will decrease g(p*)−g(p cj ) owing to convexity and the definition of p*.

  • Component C will stay the same or decrease. We remain within the loss threshold for the time period where we charge the higher p cj . This also results in a higher reference price for the subsequent period. If r ck ′+ρp ck > 0, then Component C will decrease. The same is true for subsequent price increases.

In all cases, the increase to at least the minimum of r cm +ρ and p* increases average profit.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

von Massow, M., Hassini, E. Pricing strategy in the presence of reference prices with thresholds. J Revenue Pricing Manag 12, 339–359 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1057/rpm.2013.1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/rpm.2013.1

Keywords

Navigation